Jump to content

Instant-runoff voting: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
mNo edit summary
No edit summary
Line 2: Line 2:
{{for|the proportional electoral system applying ranked ballots to multi-member constituencies|Single transferable vote}}
{{for|the proportional electoral system applying ranked ballots to multi-member constituencies|Single transferable vote}}
{{Use dmy dates|date=February 2024}}
{{Use dmy dates|date=February 2024}}
{{Electoral systems}}


'''Instant-runoff voting''' ('''IRV'''), also known as '''plurality with elimination''' or '''sequential loser plurality''',<ref>{{Cite web |last=Koether |first=Robb T. |title=The Plurality-with-Elimination Method |url=https://people.hsc.edu/faculty-staff/robbk/Math111/Lectures/Fall%202017/Lecture%209%20-%20The%20Plurality-with-Elimination%20Method.pdf#:~:text=By%20the%20plurality-with-elimination%20method%20%28also%20called%20instant-runoff%20voting%2C,the%20remaining%20candidates%20until%20there%20is%20a%20winner.}}</ref> is a [[Ranked voting|ranked-choice voting system]] that modifies plurality by introducing last-candidate elimination.<ref name="autogenerated1">{{cite book |title=Robert's Rules of Order Newly Revised |last=Robert |first=Henry |publisher=Da Capo Press |year=2011 |isbn=978-0-306-82020-5 |edition=11th |pages=425–428}}</ref><ref name="Mt Holyoke">{{cite web |date=8 April 2005 |title=Types of Voting Systems |url=http://www.mtholyoke.edu/acad/polit/damy/BeginnningReading/types.htm |access-date=6 May 2010 |publisher=Mtholyoke.edu}}</ref> In the United Kingdom, it is generally called the '''alternative vote''' ('''AV''').<ref>{{cite web |url=https://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/voting-systems/types-of-voting-system/alternative-vote/ |title=Alternative Vote |website=www.electoral-reform.org.uk |access-date=30 May 2019}}</ref> [[Ranked-choice voting in the United States|In the United States]] and Australia, IRV is sometimes referred to simply as '''ranked-choice voting''' ('''RCV''')<ref>{{cite web |last=FairVote.org |title=Ranked Choice Voting / Instant Runoff |url=https://www.fairvote.org/rcv |access-date=30 May 2019 |website=FairVote}}</ref> or '''preferential voting'''<ref>{{cite web |title=Explainer: What is preferential voting? |url=https://www.sbs.com.au/news/explainer-what-is-preferential-voting |access-date=30 May 2019 |website=SBS News}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |title=Preferential voting |url=https://www.aec.gov.au/learn/preferential-voting.htm |access-date=17 November 2020 |website=Australian Electoral Commission}}</ref> respectively, though such terms are considered [[Misnomer|misnomers]] because of the wide variety of [[Ranked voting|ranked-choice (preferential) voting systems]] other than IRV.
'''Instant-runoff voting''' ('''IRV'''), also known as '''plurality with elimination''' or '''sequential loser plurality''',<ref>{{Cite web |last=Koether |first=Robb T. |title=The Plurality-with-Elimination Method |url=https://people.hsc.edu/faculty-staff/robbk/Math111/Lectures/Fall%202017/Lecture%209%20-%20The%20Plurality-with-Elimination%20Method.pdf#:~:text=By%20the%20plurality-with-elimination%20method%20%28also%20called%20instant-runoff%20voting%2C,the%20remaining%20candidates%20until%20there%20is%20a%20winner.}}</ref> is a [[Ranked voting|ranked-choice voting system]] that modifies plurality by introducing last-candidate elimination.<ref name="autogenerated12">{{cite book |last=Robert |first=Henry |title=Robert's Rules of Order Newly Revised |publisher=Da Capo Press |year=2011 |isbn=978-0-306-82020-5 |edition=11th |pages=425–428}}</ref><ref name="Mt Holyoke2">{{cite web |date=8 April 2005 |title=Types of Voting Systems |url=http://www.mtholyoke.edu/acad/polit/damy/BeginnningReading/types.htm |access-date=6 May 2010 |publisher=Mtholyoke.edu}}</ref> In the United Kingdom, it is generally called the '''alternative vote''' ('''AV''').<ref>{{cite web |title=Alternative Vote |url=https://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/voting-systems/types-of-voting-system/alternative-vote/ |access-date=30 May 2019 |website=www.electoral-reform.org.uk}}</ref> [[Ranked-choice voting in the United States|In the United States]] and Australia, IRV is sometimes incorrectly referred to as '''ranked-choice voting''' ('''RCV''')<ref>{{cite web |last=FairVote.org |title=Ranked Choice Voting / Instant Runoff |url=https://www.fairvote.org/rcv |access-date=30 May 2019 |website=FairVote}}</ref> or '''preferential voting'''<ref>{{cite web |title=Explainer: What is preferential voting? |url=https://www.sbs.com.au/news/explainer-what-is-preferential-voting |access-date=30 May 2019 |website=SBS News}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |title=Preferential voting |url=https://www.aec.gov.au/learn/preferential-voting.htm |access-date=17 November 2020 |website=Australian Electoral Commission}}</ref> respectively, as a result of conflation with the class of all [[Ranked voting|ranked-choice (preferential) voting systems]].


IRV elections are a virtual (instant) variation on [[Exhaustive ballot|multiple-round voting]]. In each round, voters choose a favourite candidate; the last-place finisher is eliminated and another round is held. IRV elections automate this process by having voters rank candidates from first to last in order of preference. Voting can then be completed "instantly" by automatically reassigning each voter's ballot to their ''alternate'' (i.e. second) choice. This process continues until every candidate except one has been eliminated, at which point they are declared the winner.
IRV elections are a virtual (instant) variation on [[Exhaustive ballot|multiple-round voting]]. In each round, voters choose a favourite candidate; the last-place finisher is eliminated and another round is held. IRV elections automate this process by having voters rank candidates from first to last in order of preference. Voting can then be completed "instantly" by automatically reassigning each voter's ballot to their ''alternate'' (i.e. second) choice. This process continues until every candidate except one has been eliminated, at which point they are declared the winner.


IRV is [[history and use of instant-runoff voting|used in national elections in several countries]]. In Australia, it is used to elect members of the federal [[Australian House of Representatives|House of Representatives]],<ref name="Australian Electoral Commission">{{cite web |url=http://www.aec.gov.au/ |title=Australian Electoral Commission |publisher=Aec.gov.au |date=23 April 2014 |access-date=30 April 2014}}</ref> as well as the lower houses in most states, and in some local government elections. It is the method used to elect the [[President of India#Election process|president of India]], the [[president of Ireland]],<ref name="International Constitutional Law">{{cite web |url=http://www.servat.unibe.ch/icl/ei00000_.html |title=Ireland Constitution, Article 12(2.3) |publisher=International Constitutional Law |year=1995 |access-date=15 February 2008}}</ref> and (in a modified form) the [[National Parliament of Papua New Guinea]].<ref>{{Cite web |title=Understanding the Limited Preferential Voting system – EMTV Online |date=10 April 2017 |url=https://emtv.com.pg/understanding-the-limited-preferential-voting-system/ |access-date=18 February 2021}}</ref> When used in city elections, the mayor is often elected through IRV.<ref>Rek, Municipal Elections in Edmonton</ref> It is also used in choosing the [[Academy Award for Best Picture]],{{Cn|date=February 2024}} and [[Exhaustive ballot|a non-instant variant]] is used for the TV show ''[[American Idol]]''.{{Cn|date=February 2024}}
IRV is [[History and use of instant-runoff voting|used in national elections in several countries]]. In Australia, it is used to elect members of the federal [[Australian House of Representatives|House of Representatives]],<ref name="Australian Electoral Commission2">{{cite web |date=23 April 2014 |title=Australian Electoral Commission |url=http://www.aec.gov.au/ |access-date=30 April 2014 |publisher=Aec.gov.au}}</ref> as well as the lower houses in most states, and in some local government elections. It is the method used to elect the [[President of India#Election process|president of India]], the [[president of Ireland]],<ref name="International Constitutional Law2">{{cite web |year=1995 |title=Ireland Constitution, Article 12(2.3) |url=http://www.servat.unibe.ch/icl/ei00000_.html |access-date=15 February 2008 |publisher=International Constitutional Law}}</ref> and (in a modified form) the [[National Parliament of Papua New Guinea]].<ref>{{Cite web |date=10 April 2017 |title=Understanding the Limited Preferential Voting system – EMTV Online |url=https://emtv.com.pg/understanding-the-limited-preferential-voting-system/ |access-date=18 February 2021}}</ref> When used in city elections, the mayor is often elected through IRV.<ref>Rek, Municipal Elections in Edmonton</ref> It is also used in choosing the [[Academy Award for Best Picture]],{{Cn|date=February 2024}} and [[Exhaustive ballot|a non-instant variant]] is used for the TV show ''[[American Idol]]''{{Cn|date=February 2024}}.


==Election procedure==
==Election procedure==
Line 24: Line 23:


==Terminology==
==Terminology==
Instant-runoff voting derives its name from the way the ballot count simulates a series of runoffs, similar to an [[Exhaustive ballot|exhaustive ballot system]], except that voter preferences do not change between rounds.<ref name="publications.parliament.uk">{{cite web |date=15 February 2001 |title=Second Report: Election of a Speaker |url=https://publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm200001/cmselect/cmproced/40/4005.htm |access-date=18 February 2008 |publisher=House of Commons Select Committee on Procedure}}<!--This ref describes similarities/differences between IRV and exhaustive ballot.--></ref> It is also known as the alternative vote, transferable vote, ranked-choice voting (RCV), single-seat ranked-choice voting, or preferential voting.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Cary |first=David |date=1 January 2011 |title=Estimating the Margin of Victory for Instant-runoff Voting |url=http://dl.acm.org/citation.cfm?id=2028012.2028015 |journal=Proceedings of the 2011 Conference on Electronic Voting Technology/Workshop on Trustworthy Elections |series=EVT/WOTE'11 |pages=3}}</ref>
Instant-runoff voting derives its name from the way the ballot count simulates a series of runoffs, similar to an [[Exhaustive ballot|exhaustive ballot system]], except that voter preferences do not change between rounds.<ref name="publications.parliament.uk2">{{cite web |date=15 February 2001 |title=Second Report: Election of a Speaker |url=https://publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm200001/cmselect/cmproced/40/4005.htm |access-date=18 February 2008 |publisher=House of Commons Select Committee on Procedure}}<!--This ref describes similarities/differences between IRV and exhaustive ballot.--></ref> It is also known as the alternative vote, transferable vote, ranked-choice voting (RCV), single-seat ranked-choice voting, or preferential voting.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Cary |first=David |date=1 January 2011 |title=Estimating the Margin of Victory for Instant-runoff Voting |url=http://dl.acm.org/citation.cfm?id=2028012.2028015 |journal=Proceedings of the 2011 Conference on Electronic Voting Technology/Workshop on Trustworthy Elections |series=EVT/WOTE'11 |pages=3}}</ref>


Britons and New Zealanders generally call IRV the "alternative vote" (AV).<ref>{{cite web |date=8 February 2012 |title=BBC News – Alternative vote |url=https://www.bbc.com/news/uk-politics-12910547 |access-date=9 October 2019 |website=bbc.com |publisher=British Broadcasting Corporation}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |date=30 September 2017 |title=Opinion: OUSA Needs the Alternative Vote |url=https://www.critic.co.nz/news/article/7194/opinion-ousa-needs-the-alternative-vote |access-date=9 October 2019 |website=Critic – Te Arohi |publisher=Otago University Students' Association |location=Otago, New Zealand}}</ref> while in Canada it is called "ranked choice voting".<ref>{{cite web |title=What is Ranked Choice Voting? |url=http://www.london.ca/city-hall/elections/ranked-choice-voting/Pages/What-is-Ranked-Choice-Voting.aspx |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180226101409/http://www.london.ca/city-hall/elections/ranked-choice-voting/Pages/What-is-Ranked-Choice-Voting.aspx |archive-date=26 February 2018 |website=City of London}}</ref> Australians, who use IRV for most single winner elections, call IRV "preferential voting".<ref>{{cite news |date=11 December 2020 |title=Liberal plan to change federal voting laws may have crossbench support |work=The Guardian |url=https://www.theguardian.com/australia-news/2020/dec/12/liberal-plan-to-change-federal-voting-laws-may-have-crossbench-support |access-date=13 February 2021}}</ref> Jurisdictions using IRV such as [[San Francisco]], California, Maine, Alaska, and Minneapolis, Minnesota have codified the term "ranked choice voting" in their laws. The San Francisco Department of Elections claimed the word "instant" in the term "instant runoff voting" could confuse voters into expecting results to be immediately available.<ref>Appendix D, Instant Runoff Voting, San Francisco Charter § 13.102 https://sfgov.org/ccsfgsa/sites/default/files/Voting%20Systems%20Task%20Force/AppendixD__.pdf.</ref><ref>{{cite web |last=Arntz |first=John |date=2 February 2005 |title=Ranked-Choice Voting: A Guide for Candidates |url=http://www.fairvote.org/media/irv/sanfrancisco/RCVCandidateGuide04.pdf |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20081202040611/http://fairvote.org/media/irv/sanfrancisco/RCVCandidateGuide04.pdf |archive-date=2 December 2008 |access-date=25 August 2009 |publisher=Department of Elections: City and County of San Francisco |via=[[FairVote]] |quote=In San Francisco, ranked-choice voting is sometimes called 'instant run-off voting.' The Department of Elections generally uses the term ranked-choice voting, because it describes the voting method—voters are directed to rank their first-, second- and third-choice candidates. The Department also uses the term ranked-choice voting because the word 'instant' might create an expectation that final results will be available immediately after the polls close on election night.}}</ref>
Britons and New Zealanders generally call IRV the "alternative vote" (AV).<ref>{{cite web |date=8 February 2012 |title=BBC News – Alternative vote |url=https://www.bbc.com/news/uk-politics-12910547 |access-date=9 October 2019 |website=bbc.com |publisher=British Broadcasting Corporation}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |date=30 September 2017 |title=Opinion: OUSA Needs the Alternative Vote |url=https://www.critic.co.nz/news/article/7194/opinion-ousa-needs-the-alternative-vote |access-date=9 October 2019 |website=Critic – Te Arohi |publisher=Otago University Students' Association |location=Otago, New Zealand}}</ref>. Australians, who use IRV for most single winner elections, call IRV "preferential voting".<ref>{{cite news |date=11 December 2020 |title=Liberal plan to change federal voting laws may have crossbench support |url=https://www.theguardian.com/australia-news/2020/dec/12/liberal-plan-to-change-federal-voting-laws-may-have-crossbench-support |access-date=13 February 2021 |work=The Guardian}}</ref>


IRV is occasionally referred to (rather confusingly) either as Hare's method<ref>{{Cite encyclopedia |date=24 June 2019 |editor1-last=Zalta |editor1-first=Edward N. |last=Pacuit |first=Eric |orig-date=3 August 2011 |title=Voting Methods |encyclopedia=The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy |edition=Fall 2019 |url=https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/fall2019/entries/voting-methods/ |via=plato.stanford.edu}}</ref> (after [[Thomas Hare (political scientist)|Thomas Hare]]) or as Ware's method, after the American [[William Robert Ware]], to differentiate it from other ranked-choice voting methods such as Condorcet, Borda, or Bucklin voting. American NGO [[FairVote]] uses the terminology "ranked choice voting" to refer to IRV in the case of single-winner offices, a choice that has caused controversy because it conflates instant runoff with {{what|date=February 2024}}.<ref>{{cite web |date=17 August 2019 |title=How RCV Works |url=https://www.fairvote.org/rcv#how_rcv_works |access-date=17 August 2018 |website=FairVote}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |title=What is Ranked Choice Voting? |url=http://www.london.ca/city-hall/elections/ranked-choice-voting/Pages/What-is-Ranked-Choice-Voting.aspx |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180226101409/http://www.london.ca/city-hall/elections/ranked-choice-voting/Pages/What-is-Ranked-Choice-Voting.aspx |archive-date=26 February 2018 |website=City of London}}</ref>
Jurisdictions in the United States IRV such as [[San Francisco]], [[Minneapolis]], [[Maine]], and [[Alaska]], have tended to use the term "ranked choice voting" in their laws. The San Francisco Department of Elections claimed the word "instant" in the term "instant runoff voting" could confuse voters into expecting results to be immediately available.<ref>Appendix D, Instant Runoff Voting, San Francisco Charter § 13.102 https://sfgov.org/ccsfgsa/sites/default/files/Voting%20Systems%20Task%20Force/AppendixD__.pdf.</ref><ref>{{cite web |last=Arntz |first=John |date=2 February 2005 |title=Ranked-Choice Voting: A Guide for Candidates |url=http://www.fairvote.org/media/irv/sanfrancisco/RCVCandidateGuide04.pdf |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20081202040611/http://fairvote.org/media/irv/sanfrancisco/RCVCandidateGuide04.pdf |archive-date=2 December 2008 |access-date=25 August 2009 |publisher=Department of Elections: City and County of San Francisco |via=[[FairVote]] |quote=In San Francisco, ranked-choice voting is sometimes called 'instant run-off voting.' The Department of Elections generally uses the term ranked-choice voting, because it describes the voting method—voters are directed to rank their first-, second- and third-choice candidates. The Department also uses the term ranked-choice voting because the word 'instant' might create an expectation that final results will be available immediately after the polls close on election night.}}</ref> As a result of American influence, the term ranked-choice voting is often used in Canada as well.<ref>{{cite web |title=What is Ranked Choice Voting? |url=http://www.london.ca/city-hall/elections/ranked-choice-voting/Pages/What-is-Ranked-Choice-Voting.aspx |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180226101409/http://www.london.ca/city-hall/elections/ranked-choice-voting/Pages/What-is-Ranked-Choice-Voting.aspx |archive-date=26 February 2018 |website=City of London}}</ref> American NGO [[FairVote]] has promoted the terminology "ranked choice voting" to refer to IRV, a choice that has caused controversy and accusations that the organization is attempting to obscure the existence of other [[Ranked-choice|ranked voting]] methods that could otherwise compete with IRV.<ref>{{cite web |date=17 August 2019 |title=How RCV Works |url=https://www.fairvote.org/rcv#how_rcv_works |access-date=17 August 2018 |website=FairVote}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |title=What is Ranked Choice Voting? |url=http://www.london.ca/city-hall/elections/ranked-choice-voting/Pages/What-is-Ranked-Choice-Voting.aspx |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180226101409/http://www.london.ca/city-hall/elections/ranked-choice-voting/Pages/What-is-Ranked-Choice-Voting.aspx |archive-date=26 February 2018 |website=City of London}}</ref>

IRV is occasionally referred to either as Hare's method<ref>{{Cite encyclopedia |title=Voting Methods |encyclopedia=The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy |url=https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/fall2019/entries/voting-methods/ |last=Pacuit |first=Eric |date=24 June 2019 |orig-date=3 August 2011 |editor1-last=Zalta |editor1-first=Edward N. |edition=Fall 2019 |via=plato.stanford.edu}}</ref> (after [[Thomas Hare (political scientist)|Thomas Hare]]) or as Ware's method, after the American [[William Robert Ware]], to differentiate it from other ranked-choice voting methods such as Condorcet, Borda, or Bucklin voting.


When the [[single transferable vote]] (STV) method is applied to a single-winner election, it becomes IRV; the government of Ireland has called IRV "proportional representation" based on the fact that the same ballot form is used to elect its president by IRV and parliamentary seats by proportional representation (STV), but IRV is a non-proportional winner-take-all (single-winner) election method while STV elects multiple winners.<ref>{{cite web |title=Proportional Representation |url=https://www.citizensinformation.ie/en/government_in_ireland/elections_and_referenda/voting/proportional_representation.html |access-date=17 August 2019 |publisher=Citizens Information Board}}</ref> State law in [[South Carolina]]<ref>{{cite web |title=South Carolina General Assembly : 116th Session, 2005–2006 |url=http://www.scstatehouse.gov/sess116_2005-2006/bills/3720.doc |access-date=1 March 2015 |publisher=Scstatehouse.gov}}</ref> and [[Arkansas]]<ref>{{cite web |title=Bill Information |url=http://www.arkleg.state.ar.us/assembly/2005/R/Pages/BillInformation.aspx?measureno=HB1770 |access-date=28 January 2015 |publisher=Arkleg.state.ar.us}}</ref> use "instant runoff" to describe the practice of having certain categories of absentee voters cast ranked-choice ballots before the first round of an election and counting those ballots in any subsequent runoff elections.
When the [[single transferable vote]] (STV) method is applied to a single-winner election, it becomes IRV; the government of Ireland has called IRV "proportional representation" based on the fact that the same ballot form is used to elect its president by IRV and parliamentary seats by proportional representation (STV), but IRV is a non-proportional winner-take-all (single-winner) election method while STV elects multiple winners.<ref>{{cite web |title=Proportional Representation |url=https://www.citizensinformation.ie/en/government_in_ireland/elections_and_referenda/voting/proportional_representation.html |access-date=17 August 2019 |publisher=Citizens Information Board}}</ref> State law in [[South Carolina]]<ref>{{cite web |title=South Carolina General Assembly : 116th Session, 2005–2006 |url=http://www.scstatehouse.gov/sess116_2005-2006/bills/3720.doc |access-date=1 March 2015 |publisher=Scstatehouse.gov}}</ref> and [[Arkansas]]<ref>{{cite web |title=Bill Information |url=http://www.arkleg.state.ar.us/assembly/2005/R/Pages/BillInformation.aspx?measureno=HB1770 |access-date=28 January 2015 |publisher=Arkleg.state.ar.us}}</ref> use "instant runoff" to describe the practice of having certain categories of absentee voters cast ranked-choice ballots before the first round of an election and counting those ballots in any subsequent runoff elections.


==Properties, advantages, and disadvantages==
==Properties, advantages, and disadvantages==

=== Wasted votes and Condorcet winners ===
=== Wasted votes and Condorcet winners ===
Compared to a plurality voting system that rewards only the top vote-getter, instant-runoff voting mitigates the problem of [[wasted vote]]s.<ref name="chamberlin">J. R. Chamberlin and M. D. Cohen, ‘Toward Applicable Social Choice Theory...’, (1978).</ref> However, it does not eliminate this problem, or ensure the election of a [[Condorcet winner criterion|Condorcet winner]], which is the candidate who would win a direct election against any other candidate in the race. These issues are illustrated in the following election:
Compared to a plurality voting system that rewards only the top vote-getter, instant-runoff voting mitigates the problem of [[Wasted vote|wasted votes]].<ref name="chamberlin2">J. R. Chamberlin and M. D. Cohen, ‘Toward Applicable Social Choice Theory...’, (1978).</ref> However, it does not eliminate this problem, or ensure the election of a [[Condorcet winner criterion|Condorcet winner]], which is the candidate who would win a direct election against any other candidate in the race. These issues are illustrated in the following election:
[[File:IRVCopeland.png|thumb|upright=1.2|In IRV for a polarized election between left, right, and center, the votes for B are not wasted, but the consensus candidate (B) is not elected]]
[[File:IRVCopeland.png|thumb|In IRV for a polarized election between left, right, and center, the votes for B are not wasted, but the consensus candidate (B) is not elected]]
{| class="wikitable"
{| class="wikitable"
|+ Simple election example
|+Simple election example
| style="text-align:left; font-weight: bold;" | First choice
|First choice
! A
!A
! colspan="2" | B
! colspan="2" |B
! C
!C
|-
|-
| style="text-align:left; font-weight: bold;" | Second choice
|Second choice
! B
!B
! A
!A
! C
!C
! B
!B
|-
|-
!Voters
! style="text-align:left;" | Voters
|36%
| 36% || 10%|| 20% || 34%
|10%
|20%
|34%
|}
|}

* A wins plurality vote: second place preferences are ignored, so candidate A wins with 36 percent of the vote as against 34 percent for C and 30 percent (10+20) for B.
* A wins plurality vote: second place preferences are ignored, so candidate A wins with 36 percent of the vote as against 34 percent for C and 30 percent (10+20) for B.
* C wins IRV vote: candidate B gets the fewest first place votes so is eliminated in the first round. Candidate C gets more of B's second choice preferences than candidate A, winning the second round by 54 percent (20+34) to 46 percent (36+10). This result is the same as would occur if there was a primary with 3 candidates and a general election with the two remaining candidates (assuming no voters changed their preferences before the general election). Every voter gets a say in the final runoff, so no votes are wasted.
* C wins IRV vote: candidate B gets the fewest first place votes so is eliminated in the first round. Candidate C gets more of B's second choice preferences than candidate A, winning the second round by 54 percent (20+34) to 46 percent (36+10). This result is the same as would occur if there was a primary with 3 candidates and a general election with the two remaining candidates (assuming no voters changed their preferences before the general election). Every voter gets a say in the final runoff, so no votes are wasted.
* B wins [[Condorcet method]]s, for instance in IRV: in the first round candidates B and C are in last place, so they go head to head. Candidate A's second place votes go to candidate B, so candidate B wins 66 percent (36+10+20) to 34 percent over candidate C. In the second runoff round candidate C has been eliminated so candidates A and B go head to head. Candidate C's second place votes go to candidate B, so candidate B wins 64 percent (10+20+34) to 36 percent over candidate A. This can happen in a scenario where candidate B is a compromise candidate between polarizing candidates A and C.
* B wins [[Condorcet method|Condorcet methods]], for instance in IRV: in the first round candidates B and C are in last place, so they go head to head. Candidate A's second place votes go to candidate B, so candidate B wins 66 percent (36+10+20) to 34 percent over candidate C. In the second runoff round candidate C has been eliminated so candidates A and B go head to head. Candidate C's second place votes go to candidate B, so candidate B wins 64 percent (10+20+34) to 36 percent over candidate A. This can happen in a scenario where candidate B is a compromise candidate between polarizing candidates A and C.


===Invalid, incomplete and exhausted ballots===
===Invalid, incomplete and exhausted ballots===
Line 76: Line 80:
The [[Gibbard–Satterthwaite theorem]] demonstrates that no (deterministic, non-dictatorial) voting method using only the preference rankings of the voters can be entirely immune from tactical voting. This implies that IRV is susceptible to tactical voting in some circumstances.
The [[Gibbard–Satterthwaite theorem]] demonstrates that no (deterministic, non-dictatorial) voting method using only the preference rankings of the voters can be entirely immune from tactical voting. This implies that IRV is susceptible to tactical voting in some circumstances.


Research concludes that IRV is one of the voting methods least vulnerable to tactical voting, with theorist [[Nicolaus Tideman]] noting that, "alternative voting is quite resistant to strategy",<ref name="tac1">{{cite journal |last1=Bartholdi III |first1=John J. | author-link2=James B. Orlin |last2=Orlin |first2=James B. |year=1991 |title=Single transferable vote resists strategic voting |url=http://www.isye.gatech.edu/~jjb/papers/stv.pdf |journal=Social Choice and Welfare |volume=8 |issue=4 |pages=341–354 |doi=10.1007/bf00183045 |citeseerx=10.1.1.127.97 |s2cid=17749613}}</ref> and Australian political analyst [[Antony Green]] dismissing suggestions of tactical voting.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://blogs.abc.net.au/antonygreen/2010/07/how-to-vote-guide.html |title=How to Vote Guide |date=11 October 2011 |website=Antony Green's Election Blog |access-date=29 January 2017 |quote=What is the best way to vote strategically? The best strategic vote is to number the candidates in the order you would like to see them elected.&nbsp;... in electorate of more than 90,000 voters, and without perfect knowledge, such a strategy is not possible.}}</ref> James Green-Armytage tested four ranked-choice methods, and found the alternative vote to be the second-most-resistant to tactical voting, though it was beaten by a class of AV-[[Condorcet method|Condorcet]] hybrids, and did not resist strategic withdrawal by candidates well.<ref name="jga">{{cite web |url=http://www.econ.ucsb.edu/~armytage/hybrids.pdf |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130603013310/http://www.econ.ucsb.edu/~armytage/hybrids.pdf |archive-date=3 June 2013 |first=James |last=Green-Armytage |title=Four Condorcet-Hare Hybrid Methods for Single-Winner Elections |access-date=31 May 2011}}</ref> These analyses only apply to tactical voting, but not to other forms of manipulation; for example, Tideman and Robinette demonstrate a method by which a candidate modifies their campaign to appeal to a slightly broader range of voters, including those of a popular opponent, so as to "bracket" that opponent out (cause them to be eliminated earlier).<ref name="robinette2020">{{cite conference |first1=Robbie |last1=Robinette |first2=Nicolaus |last2=Tideman |title=What a Difference a Voting Rule Makes |place=Savannah, Georgia |date=12 March 2021 |url=https://publicchoicesociety.org/conference/2021/conference-program/2021-03-12}}</ref>
Research concludes that IRV is one of the voting methods least vulnerable to tactical voting, with theorist [[Nicolaus Tideman]] noting that, "alternative voting is quite resistant to strategy",<ref name="tac12">{{cite journal |last1=Bartholdi III |first1=John J. |last2=Orlin |first2=James B. |author-link2=James B. Orlin |year=1991 |title=Single transferable vote resists strategic voting |url=http://www.isye.gatech.edu/~jjb/papers/stv.pdf |journal=Social Choice and Welfare |volume=8 |issue=4 |pages=341–354 |citeseerx=10.1.1.127.97 |doi=10.1007/bf00183045 |s2cid=17749613}}</ref> and Australian political analyst [[Antony Green]] dismissing suggestions of tactical voting.<ref>{{cite web |date=11 October 2011 |title=How to Vote Guide |url=http://blogs.abc.net.au/antonygreen/2010/07/how-to-vote-guide.html |access-date=29 January 2017 |website=Antony Green's Election Blog |quote=What is the best way to vote strategically? The best strategic vote is to number the candidates in the order you would like to see them elected.&nbsp;... in electorate of more than 90,000 voters, and without perfect knowledge, such a strategy is not possible.}}</ref> James Green-Armytage tested four ranked-choice methods, and found the alternative vote to be the second-most-resistant to tactical voting, though it was beaten by a class of AV-[[Condorcet method|Condorcet]] hybrids, and did not resist strategic withdrawal by candidates well.<ref name="jga2">{{cite web |last=Green-Armytage |first=James |title=Four Condorcet-Hare Hybrid Methods for Single-Winner Elections |url=http://www.econ.ucsb.edu/~armytage/hybrids.pdf |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130603013310/http://www.econ.ucsb.edu/~armytage/hybrids.pdf |archive-date=3 June 2013 |access-date=31 May 2011}}</ref> These analyses only apply to tactical voting, but not to other forms of manipulation; for example, Tideman and Robinette demonstrate a method by which a candidate modifies their campaign to appeal to a slightly broader range of voters, including those of a popular opponent, so as to "bracket" that opponent out (cause them to be eliminated earlier).<ref name="robinette20202">{{cite conference |last1=Robinette |first1=Robbie |last2=Tideman |first2=Nicolaus |date=12 March 2021 |title=What a Difference a Voting Rule Makes |url=https://publicchoicesociety.org/conference/2021/conference-program/2021-03-12 |place=Savannah, Georgia}}</ref>


By not meeting the monotonicity, [[Condorcet winner criterion|Condorcet winner]], and [[Participation criterion|participation criteria]], IRV may incentivize forms of [[tactical voting]] (such as [[Tactical voting#Types of strategic voting|compromising]]) when voters have sufficient information about other voters' preferences, such as from accurate pre-election polling.<ref name="tac3" /> [[FairVote]] mentions that [[Monotonicity criterion|monotonicity]] failure can lead to situations where "having more voters rank [a] candidate first, can cause [the candidate] to switch from being a winner to being a loser".<ref>{{cite web |url=http://archive.fairvote.org/?page=2261 |title=Monotonicity and IRV – Why the Monotonicity Criterion is of Little Import |publisher=Archive.fairvote.org |access-date=17 April 2011}}</ref> This occurs when a [[Mutual majority criterion|mutual majority]] exists which would elect a different candidate than the Condorcet candidate and a minority coalition running off to a single candidate exceeds one-half the size of this majority: the minority candidate cannot be eliminated until the mutual majority runs off to a majority winner. Moving the winner to the top of the minority ballots can shrink the minority sufficiently for their candidate to be eliminated, and their votes then cause the election of a different candidate.
By not meeting the monotonicity, [[Condorcet winner criterion|Condorcet winner]], and [[Participation criterion|participation criteria]], IRV may incentivize forms of [[tactical voting]] (such as [[Tactical voting#Types of strategic voting|compromising]]) when voters have sufficient information about other voters' preferences, such as from accurate pre-election polling.<ref name="tac32">Warren Smith (2009) [http://rangevoting.org/Burlington.html "Burlington Vermont 2009 IRV mayor election; Thwarted-majority, non-monotonicity & other failures (oops)"]</ref> [[FairVote]] mentions that [[Monotonicity criterion|monotonicity]] failure can lead to situations where "having more voters rank [a] candidate first, can cause [the candidate] to switch from being a winner to being a loser".<ref>{{cite web |title=Monotonicity and IRV – Why the Monotonicity Criterion is of Little Import |url=http://archive.fairvote.org/?page=2261 |access-date=17 April 2011 |publisher=Archive.fairvote.org}}</ref> This occurs when a [[Mutual majority criterion|mutual majority]] exists which would elect a different candidate than the Condorcet candidate and a minority coalition running off to a single candidate exceeds one-half the size of this majority: the minority candidate cannot be eliminated until the mutual majority runs off to a majority winner. Moving the winner to the top of the minority ballots can shrink the minority sufficiently for their candidate to be eliminated, and their votes then cause the election of a different candidate.


Tactical voting in IRV seeks to alter the order of eliminations in early rounds, to ensure that the original winner is challenged by a stronger opponent in the final round. For example, in a three-party election where voters for both the [[Left-wing politics|left]] and [[Right-wing politics|right]] prefer the [[Centrism|centrist]] candidate to stop the opposing candidate from winning, those voters who care more about defeating the opposition than electing their own candidate may cast a tactical first-preference vote for the centrist candidate.
Tactical voting in IRV seeks to alter the order of eliminations in early rounds, to ensure that the original winner is challenged by a stronger opponent in the final round. For example, in a three-party election where voters for both the [[Left-wing politics|left]] and [[Right-wing politics|right]] prefer the [[Centrism|centrist]] candidate to stop the opposing candidate from winning, those voters who care more about defeating the opposition than electing their own candidate may cast a tactical first-preference vote for the centrist candidate.


The [[2009 Burlington mayoral election|2009 mayoral election in Burlington, Vermont]], provides an example in which strategy theoretically could have worked but would have been unlikely in practice. In that election, most supporters of the candidate who lost in the final round (a [[Republican Party (United States)|Republican]] who led in first choices) preferred the [[Condorcet method|Condorcet]] winner, a [[Democratic Party (United States)|Democrat]], to the IRV winner, the Progressive Party nominee. If 371 (24.7%) out of the 1,510 backers of the Republican candidate (who also preferred the Democrat over the Progressive candidate for mayor) had insincerely raised the Democrat from their second choice to their first (not changing their rankings relative to their least favourite candidate, the Progressive), the Democrat would then have advanced to the final round (instead of their favourite), defeated any opponent, and proceeded to win the IRV election.<ref name="tac3">Warren Smith (2009) [http://rangevoting.org/Burlington.html "Burlington Vermont 2009 IRV mayor election; Thwarted-majority, non-monotonicity & other failures (oops)"]</ref> This is an example of potential voter regret in that these voters who sincerely ranked their favourite candidate as first, find out after the fact that they caused the election of their least favourite candidate, which can lead to the voting tactic of [[Tactical voting#Compromising|compromising]].
The [[2009 Burlington mayoral election|2009 mayoral election in Burlington, Vermont]], provides an example in which strategy theoretically could have worked but would have been unlikely in practice. In that election, most supporters of the candidate who lost in the final round (a [[Republican Party (United States)|Republican]] who led in first choices) preferred the [[Condorcet method|Condorcet]] winner, a [[Democratic Party (United States)|Democrat]], to the IRV winner, the Progressive Party nominee. If 371 (24.7%) out of the 1,510 backers of the Republican candidate (who also preferred the Democrat over the Progressive candidate for mayor) had insincerely raised the Democrat from their second choice to their first (not changing their rankings relative to their least favourite candidate, the Progressive), the Democrat would then have advanced to the final round (instead of their favourite), defeated any opponent, and proceeded to win the IRV election.<ref name="tac32" /> This is an example of potential voter regret in that these voters who sincerely ranked their favourite candidate as first, find out after the fact that they caused the election of their least favourite candidate, which can lead to the voting tactic of [[Tactical voting#Compromising|compromising]].


==== Spoiler effect ====
==== Spoiler effect ====
{{main|Spoiler effect}}
{{main|Spoiler effect}}

The spoiler effect is when a difference is made to the anticipated outcome of an election due to the presence on the ballot paper of a candidate who will lose. Most often this is when two or more politically similar candidates divide the vote for the more popular end of the political spectrum. That is, each receives fewer votes than a single opponent on the unpopular end of the spectrum who is disliked by the majority of voters but who wins from the advantage that, on that unpopular side, they are unopposed. Strategic nomination relies on triggering this situation, and requires understanding of both the electoral process and the demographics of the district.
The spoiler effect is when a difference is made to the anticipated outcome of an election due to the presence on the ballot paper of a candidate who will lose. Most often this is when two or more politically similar candidates divide the vote for the more popular end of the political spectrum. That is, each receives fewer votes than a single opponent on the unpopular end of the spectrum who is disliked by the majority of voters but who wins from the advantage that, on that unpopular side, they are unopposed. Strategic nomination relies on triggering this situation, and requires understanding of both the electoral process and the demographics of the district.


Proponents of IRV claim that IRV eliminates the spoiler effect,<ref name=":2">{{cite web |url=http://archive.fairvote.org/factshts/irv.htm |title=Instant Run-Off Voting |website=archive.fairvote.org |access-date=29 January 2017 |quote=IRV removes the "spoiler effect" whereby minor party or independent candidates knock off major party candidates, increasing the choices available to the voters.}}</ref><ref name=":4">{{cite web |url=http://www.cfer.org/learn/irvfaq.php |title=Cal IRV FAQ |website=www.cfer.org |access-date=29 January 2017 |quote=IRV completely eliminates the 'spoiler' effect – that is, votes split between a weak and a strong candidate won't cause the strong candidate to lose if s/he is the second choice of the weak candidate's voters.}}</ref><ref name=":5">{{Cite news |url=http://www.ctnewsjunkie.com/archives/entry/op-ed_no_more_spoilers_instant_runoff_voting_makes_third_parties_viable/ |title=OP-ED {{!}} No More Spoilers? Instant Runoff Voting Makes Third Parties Viable, Improves Democracy |work=CT News Junkie |access-date=20 April 2017|quote=Instant-runoff voting ends the spoiler effect forever}}</ref><ref name=":6">{{Citation |last=CGP Grey |title=The Alternative Vote Explained |date=6 April 2011 |url=https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=3Y3jE3B8HsE&t=3m4s |quote=Alternative Vote: Stops the Spoiler Effect |access-date=20 April 2017}}</ref> since IRV makes it safe to vote honestly for marginal parties: Under a plurality method, voters who sympathize most strongly with a marginal candidate are strongly encouraged to instead vote for a more popular candidate who shares some of the same principles, since that candidate has a much greater chance of being elected and a vote for the marginal candidate will not result in the marginal candidate's election. An IRV method reduces this problem, since the voter can rank the marginal candidate first and the mainstream candidate second; in the likely event that the fringe candidate is eliminated, the vote is not wasted but is transferred to the second preference.
Proponents of IRV claim that IRV eliminates the spoiler effect,<ref name=":22">{{cite web |title=Instant Run-Off Voting |url=http://archive.fairvote.org/factshts/irv.htm |access-date=29 January 2017 |website=archive.fairvote.org |quote=IRV removes the "spoiler effect" whereby minor party or independent candidates knock off major party candidates, increasing the choices available to the voters.}}</ref><ref name=":42">{{cite web |title=Cal IRV FAQ |url=http://www.cfer.org/learn/irvfaq.php |access-date=29 January 2017 |website=www.cfer.org |quote=IRV completely eliminates the 'spoiler' effect – that is, votes split between a weak and a strong candidate won't cause the strong candidate to lose if s/he is the second choice of the weak candidate's voters.}}</ref><ref name=":52">{{Cite news |title=OP-ED {{!}} No More Spoilers? Instant Runoff Voting Makes Third Parties Viable, Improves Democracy |url=http://www.ctnewsjunkie.com/archives/entry/op-ed_no_more_spoilers_instant_runoff_voting_makes_third_parties_viable/ |access-date=20 April 2017 |work=CT News Junkie |quote=Instant-runoff voting ends the spoiler effect forever}}</ref><ref name=":62">{{Citation |last=CGP Grey |title=The Alternative Vote Explained |date=6 April 2011 |url=https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=3Y3jE3B8HsE&t=3m4s |access-date=20 April 2017 |quote=Alternative Vote: Stops the Spoiler Effect}}</ref> since IRV makes it safe to vote honestly for marginal parties: Under a plurality method, voters who sympathize most strongly with a marginal candidate are strongly encouraged to instead vote for a more popular candidate who shares some of the same principles, since that candidate has a much greater chance of being elected and a vote for the marginal candidate will not result in the marginal candidate's election. An IRV method reduces this problem, since the voter can rank the marginal candidate first and the mainstream candidate second; in the likely event that the fringe candidate is eliminated, the vote is not wasted but is transferred to the second preference.


However, when the third-party candidate is more competitive, they can still act as a spoiler under IRV,<ref name=":0">{{Cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=u_XMHD4shnQC |title=Mathematics of Social Choice: Voting, Compensation, and Division |last=Borgers |first=Christoph |year=2010 |publisher=SIAM |isbn=9780898716955 |quote=Candidates C and D spoiled the election for B ... With them in the running, A won, whereas without them in the running, B would have won. ... Instant runoff voting ... does ''not'' do away with the spoiler problem entirely, although it ... makes it less likely}}</ref><ref name=":7">{{Cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=_24bJHyBV6sC |title=Gaming the Vote: Why Elections Aren't Fair (and What We Can Do About It) |last=Poundstone |first=William |year=2009 |publisher=Farrar, Straus and Giroux |isbn=9781429957649 |quote=IRV is excellent for preventing classic spoilers-minor candidates who irrationally tip the election from one major candidate to another. It is not so good when the 'spoiler' has a real chance of winning}}</ref><ref name=":8">{{Cite news |url=https://electology.org/spoiler-effect |title=The Spoiler Effect |date=20 May 2015 |newspaper=The Center for Election Science |access-date=29 January 2017}}</ref><ref name=":9">{{cite web |url=http://minguo.info/election_methods/irv |title=The Problem with Instant Runoff Voting |website=minguo.info |access-date=29 January 2017 |quote=''After'' a minor party is strong enough to win, on the other hand, a vote for them could have the same spoiler effect that it could have under the current plurality system}}</ref><ref name=":10">{{cite web |url=http://www.rangevoting.org/IRVcs.html |website=RangeVoting.org |title=Example to demonstrate how IRV leads to 'spoilers,' 2-party domination |access-date=29 January 2017 |quote=IRV means betraying your true favorite third party candidate pays off. Voting third party can mean wasting your vote under IRV, just like under plurality.}}</ref><ref name=":11">{{Citation |last=The Center for Election Science |title=Favorite Betrayal in Plurality and Instant Runoff Voting |date=2 December 2013 |url=https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=JtKAScORevQ |access-date=29 January 2017}}</ref><ref name="Burlington">{{cite journal |author=Bristow-Johnson, R. |year=2023 |title=The failure of Instant Runoff to accomplish the purpose for which it was adopted: a case study from Burlington Vermont |url=https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-023-09393-1 |format=PDF |journal=Const Polit Econ |volume=34 |issue=3 |pages=378–389 |doi=10.1007/s10602-023-09393-1 |s2cid=255657135 |access-date=9 January 2024}}</ref> by taking away first-choice votes from the more mainstream candidate until that candidate is eliminated, and then that candidate's second-choice votes helping a more-disliked candidate to win. In these scenarios, it would have been better for the third party voters if their candidate had not run at all (spoiler effect), or if they had voted dishonestly, ranking their favourite second rather than first (favourite betrayal).<ref>{{Cite journal |last=O'Neill |first=Jeffrey C. |date=2006 |title=Everything That Can be Counted Does Not Necessarily Count: The Right to Vote and the Choice of a Voting System |journal=SSRN Working Paper Series |url=http://www.ssrn.com/abstract=883058 |page=340 |doi=10.2139/ssrn.883058 |s2cid=155750146 |issn=1556-5068 |quote=With instant runoff voting ... The strategy for the liberal voter is the same as for plurality voting: Her favorite candidate cannot win, so she casts her vote for her favorite candidate with a realistic chance of winning}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |url=https://www.cato-unbound.org/2016/12/09/jason-sorens/false-promise-instant-runoff-voting |title=The False Promise of Instant Runoff Voting |last=Comments |date=9 December 2016 |website=Cato Unbound |access-date=29 January 2017 |quote=They'll have a strategic incentive to falsify their preferences.}}</ref> This is the same bracketing effect exploited by Robinette and Tideman in their research on strategic campaigning, where a candidate alters their campaign to cause a change in voter honest choice, resulting in the elimination of a candidate who nevertheless remains more preferred by voters.
However, when the third-party candidate is more competitive, they can still act as a spoiler under IRV,<ref name=":04">{{Cite book |last=Borgers |first=Christoph |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=u_XMHD4shnQC |title=Mathematics of Social Choice: Voting, Compensation, and Division |publisher=SIAM |year=2010 |isbn=9780898716955 |quote=Candidates C and D spoiled the election for B ... With them in the running, A won, whereas without them in the running, B would have won. ... Instant runoff voting ... does ''not'' do away with the spoiler problem entirely, although it ... makes it less likely}}</ref><ref name=":72">{{Cite book |last=Poundstone |first=William |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=_24bJHyBV6sC |title=Gaming the Vote: Why Elections Aren't Fair (and What We Can Do About It) |publisher=Farrar, Straus and Giroux |year=2009 |isbn=9781429957649 |quote=IRV is excellent for preventing classic spoilers-minor candidates who irrationally tip the election from one major candidate to another. It is not so good when the 'spoiler' has a real chance of winning}}</ref><ref name=":82">{{Cite news |date=20 May 2015 |title=The Spoiler Effect |url=https://electology.org/spoiler-effect |access-date=29 January 2017 |newspaper=The Center for Election Science}}</ref><ref name=":92">{{cite web |title=The Problem with Instant Runoff Voting |url=http://minguo.info/election_methods/irv |access-date=29 January 2017 |website=minguo.info |quote=''After'' a minor party is strong enough to win, on the other hand, a vote for them could have the same spoiler effect that it could have under the current plurality system}}</ref><ref name=":102">{{cite web |title=Example to demonstrate how IRV leads to 'spoilers,' 2-party domination |url=http://www.rangevoting.org/IRVcs.html |access-date=29 January 2017 |website=RangeVoting.org |quote=IRV means betraying your true favorite third party candidate pays off. Voting third party can mean wasting your vote under IRV, just like under plurality.}}</ref><ref name=":112">{{Citation |last=The Center for Election Science |title=Favorite Betrayal in Plurality and Instant Runoff Voting |date=2 December 2013 |url=https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=JtKAScORevQ |access-date=29 January 2017}}</ref><ref name="Burlington2">{{cite journal |author=Bristow-Johnson, R. |year=2023 |title=The failure of Instant Runoff to accomplish the purpose for which it was adopted: a case study from Burlington Vermont |url=https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-023-09393-1 |format=PDF |journal=Const Polit Econ |volume=34 |issue=3 |pages=378–389 |doi=10.1007/s10602-023-09393-1 |s2cid=255657135 |access-date=9 January 2024}}</ref> by taking away first-choice votes from the more mainstream candidate until that candidate is eliminated, and then that candidate's second-choice votes helping a more-disliked candidate to win. In these scenarios, it would have been better for the third party voters if their candidate had not run at all (spoiler effect), or if they had voted dishonestly, ranking their favourite second rather than first (favourite betrayal).<ref>{{Cite journal |last=O'Neill |first=Jeffrey C. |date=2006 |title=Everything That Can be Counted Does Not Necessarily Count: The Right to Vote and the Choice of a Voting System |url=http://www.ssrn.com/abstract=883058 |journal=SSRN Working Paper Series |page=340 |doi=10.2139/ssrn.883058 |issn=1556-5068 |s2cid=155750146 |quote=With instant runoff voting ... The strategy for the liberal voter is the same as for plurality voting: Her favorite candidate cannot win, so she casts her vote for her favorite candidate with a realistic chance of winning}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |last=Comments |date=9 December 2016 |title=The False Promise of Instant Runoff Voting |url=https://www.cato-unbound.org/2016/12/09/jason-sorens/false-promise-instant-runoff-voting |access-date=29 January 2017 |website=Cato Unbound |quote=They'll have a strategic incentive to falsify their preferences.}}</ref> This is the same bracketing effect exploited by Robinette and Tideman in their research on strategic campaigning, where a candidate alters their campaign to cause a change in voter honest choice, resulting in the elimination of a candidate who nevertheless remains more preferred by voters.


For example, in the [[2009 Burlington mayoral election|2009 Burlington, Vermont,mayoral election]], if the Republican candidate who lost in the final instant runoff had not run, the Democratic candidate would have defeated the winning Progressive candidate. In that sense, the Republican candidate was a spoiler—(albeit for an opposing Democrat, rather than some political ally) even though leading in first choice support.<ref name="tac3" /><ref>{{cite web |url=http://bolson.org/~bolson/2009/20090303_burlington_vt_mayor.html |title=2009 Burlington Mayor IRV Failure |website=bolson.org |access-date=29 January 2017}}</ref><ref name="Burlington" /> This also occurred in the [[2022 Alaska's at-large congressional district special election]]. If Republican [[Sarah Palin]], who lost in the final instant runoff, had not run, the more centrist Republican candidate, Nick Begich, would have defeated the winning Democratic candidate, [[Mary Peltola]].<ref>{{cite arXiv | eprint=2209.04764v1 | last1=Graham-Squire | first1=Adam | last2=McCune | first2=David | title=A Mathematical Analysis of the 2022 Alaska Special Election for US House | date=2022 | class=econ.GN }}</ref><ref>https://www.washingtonpost.com/opinions/2022/11/01/alaska-final-four-primary-begich-palin-peltola/</ref>
For example, in the [[2009 Burlington mayoral election|2009 Burlington, Vermont,mayoral election]], if the Republican candidate who lost in the final instant runoff had not run, the Democratic candidate would have defeated the winning Progressive candidate. In that sense, the Republican candidate was a spoiler—(albeit for an opposing Democrat, rather than some political ally) even though leading in first choice support.<ref name="tac32" /><ref>{{cite web |title=2009 Burlington Mayor IRV Failure |url=http://bolson.org/~bolson/2009/20090303_burlington_vt_mayor.html |access-date=29 January 2017 |website=bolson.org}}</ref><ref name="Burlington2" /> This also occurred in the [[2022 Alaska's at-large congressional district special election]]. If Republican [[Sarah Palin]], who lost in the final instant runoff, had not run, the more centrist Republican candidate, Nick Begich, would have defeated the winning Democratic candidate, [[Mary Peltola]].<ref>{{cite arXiv |eprint=2209.04764v1 |class=econ.GN |first1=Adam |last1=Graham-Squire |first2=David |last2=McCune |title=A Mathematical Analysis of the 2022 Alaska Special Election for US House |date=2022}}</ref><ref>https://www.washingtonpost.com/opinions/2022/11/01/alaska-final-four-primary-begich-palin-peltola/</ref>


In practice, IRV does not seem to discourage candidacies. In Australia's House of Representatives elections in 2007, for example, the average number of candidates in a district was seven, and at least four candidates ran in every district; notwithstanding the fact that Australia only has two major political parties. Every seat was won with a majority of the vote, including several where results would have been different under plurality voting.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://results.aec.gov.au/13745/website/HouseResultsMenu-13745.htm |title=House of Representatives Results |publisher=Results.aec.gov.au |access-date=1 March 2015}}</ref> A study of ballot image data found that all of the 138 RCV elections held in four Bay Area cities in California elected the Condorcet winner, including many with large fields of candidates and 46 where multiple rounds of counting were required to determine a winner.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.fairvote.org/every_rcv_election_in_the_bay_area_so_far_has_produced_condorcet_winners |title=Every RCV Election in the Bay Area So Far Has Produced Condorcet Winners |date=6 January 2017 |publisher=fairvote.org |access-date=13 February 2017}}</ref>
In practice, IRV does not seem to discourage candidacies. In Australia's House of Representatives elections in 2007, for example, the average number of candidates in a district was seven, and at least four candidates ran in every district; notwithstanding the fact that Australia only has two major political parties. Every seat was won with a majority of the vote, including several where results would have been different under plurality voting.<ref>{{cite web |title=House of Representatives Results |url=http://results.aec.gov.au/13745/website/HouseResultsMenu-13745.htm |access-date=1 March 2015 |publisher=Results.aec.gov.au}}</ref> A study of ballot image data found that all of the 138 RCV elections held in four Bay Area cities in California elected the Condorcet winner, including many with large fields of candidates and 46 where multiple rounds of counting were required to determine a winner.<ref>{{cite web |date=6 January 2017 |title=Every RCV Election in the Bay Area So Far Has Produced Condorcet Winners |url=http://www.fairvote.org/every_rcv_election_in_the_bay_area_so_far_has_produced_condorcet_winners |access-date=13 February 2017 |publisher=fairvote.org}}</ref>


=== Proportionality ===
=== Proportionality ===
IRV is a single-winner application of the proportional voting system known as STV, with a [[Droop quota]] (50%+1). Like all winner-take-all voting methods, IRV tends to exaggerate the number of seats won by the largest parties; small parties without majority support in any given constituency are unlikely to earn seats in a legislature, although their supporters will be more likely to be part of the final choice between the two strongest candidates.<ref name="Mt Holyoke" /> A simulation of IRV in the [[2010 United Kingdom general election|2010 UK general election]] by the [[Electoral Reform Society]] concluded that the election would have altered the balance of seats among the three main parties, but the number of seats won by minor parties would have remained unchanged.<ref>{{cite news |url=https://www.theguardian.com/politics/2010/may/10/alternative-vote-minimal-impact-general-election |access-date=1 April 2011 |date=10 May 2010 |title=Electoral reform: Alternative vote system would have had minimal impact on outcome of general election |newspaper=The Guardian |location=London |first=Alan |last=Travis}}</ref>
IRV is a single-winner application of the proportional voting system known as STV, with a [[Droop quota]] (50%+1). Like all winner-take-all voting methods, IRV tends to exaggerate the number of seats won by the largest parties; small parties without majority support in any given constituency are unlikely to earn seats in a legislature, although their supporters will be more likely to be part of the final choice between the two strongest candidates.<ref name="Mt Holyoke2" /> A simulation of IRV in the [[2010 United Kingdom general election|2010 UK general election]] by the [[Electoral Reform Society]] concluded that the election would have altered the balance of seats among the three main parties, but the number of seats won by minor parties would have remained unchanged.<ref>{{cite news |last=Travis |first=Alan |date=10 May 2010 |title=Electoral reform: Alternative vote system would have had minimal impact on outcome of general election |url=https://www.theguardian.com/politics/2010/may/10/alternative-vote-minimal-impact-general-election |access-date=1 April 2011 |newspaper=The Guardian |location=London}}</ref>


==== Australia ====
==== Australia ====
Australia, a nation with a long record of using IRV for the election of legislative bodies, has had representation in its parliament broadly similar to that expected by [[Plurality voting method|plurality methods]].
Australia, a nation with a long record of using IRV for the election of legislative bodies, has had representation in its parliament broadly similar to that expected by [[Plurality voting method|plurality methods]].


Medium-sized parties, such as the [[National Party of Australia]], can co-exist with [[Coalition (Australia)|coalition]] partners such as the [[Liberal Party of Australia]], and can compete against it without fear of losing seats to other parties due to vote splitting, although generally in practice these two parties only compete against each other when a sitting member of the coalition leaves Parliament.<ref>[http://www.abc.net.au/elections/federal/2004/guide/prefhistory.htm History of Preferential Voting in Australia], [[Australian Broadcasting Corporation]], 2004 Election Guide. "''Such a long lasting Coalition would not have been possible under first part the post voting''"</ref> IRV is more likely to result in legislatures where no single party has an absolute majority of seats (a [[hung parliament]]),{{citation needed|date=May 2011}} but does not generally produce as fragmented a legislature as a fully proportional method, such as is used for the [[House of Representatives of the Netherlands]], where coalitions of numerous small parties are needed for a majority.
Medium-sized parties, such as the [[National Party of Australia]], can co-exist with [[Coalition (Australia)|coalition]] partners such as the [[Liberal Party of Australia]], and can compete against it without fear of losing seats to other parties due to vote splitting, although generally in practice these two parties only compete against each other when a sitting member of the coalition leaves Parliament.<ref>[http://www.abc.net.au/elections/federal/2004/guide/prefhistory.htm History of Preferential Voting in Australia], [[Australian Broadcasting Corporation]], 2004 Election Guide. "''Such a long lasting Coalition would not have been possible under first part the post voting''"</ref> IRV is more likely to result in legislatures where no single party has an absolute majority of seats (a [[hung parliament]]),{{citation needed|date=May 2011}} but does not generally produce as fragmented a legislature as a fully proportional method, such as is used for the [[House of Representatives of the Netherlands]], where coalitions of numerous small parties are needed for a majority.


== Criticism ==
== Criticism ==

=== Voter confusion and legitimacy of elections ===
=== Voter confusion and legitimacy of elections ===
Some critics of IRV have noted that because of its greater complexity, IRV can create distrust among voters who misunderstand it. Often such criticism is related to allegations that IRV is a kind of [[plural voting]]. In [[Ann Arbor, Michigan|Ann Arbor]], arguments over IRV in letters to newspapers included the belief that IRV "gives minority candidate voters two votes", because some voters' ballots may count for their first choice in the first round and a lesser choice in a later round.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.migreens.org/hvgreens/aa-irv01.htm |title=History of Preferential Voting in Ann Arbor |first=Benjamin |last=Walter |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120208053837/http://migreens.org/hvgreens/aa-irv01.htm |archive-date=8 February 2012}}</ref> The argument that IRV represents [[plural voting]] is sometimes used in arguments over the "fairness" of the method, and has led to frequent legal challenges in the United States.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://archive.fairvote.org/?page=397 |title=Ann Arbor Law Suit |publisher=FairVote |access-date=10 May 2011}}</ref>
Some critics of IRV have noted that because of its greater complexity, IRV can create distrust among voters who misunderstand it. Often such criticism is related to allegations that IRV is a kind of [[plural voting]]. In [[Ann Arbor, Michigan|Ann Arbor]], arguments over IRV in letters to newspapers included the belief that IRV "gives minority candidate voters two votes", because some voters' ballots may count for their first choice in the first round and a lesser choice in a later round.<ref>{{cite web |last=Walter |first=Benjamin |title=History of Preferential Voting in Ann Arbor |url=http://www.migreens.org/hvgreens/aa-irv01.htm |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120208053837/http://migreens.org/hvgreens/aa-irv01.htm |archive-date=8 February 2012}}</ref> The argument that IRV represents [[plural voting]] is sometimes used in arguments over the "fairness" of the method, and has led to frequent legal challenges in the United States.<ref>{{cite web |title=Ann Arbor Law Suit |url=http://archive.fairvote.org/?page=397 |access-date=10 May 2011 |publisher=FairVote}}</ref>


The same argument was advanced in opposition to IRV in Maine. Governor [[Paul LePage]] claimed, ahead of the 2018 primary elections, that IRV would result in "one person, five votes", as opposed to "[[one person, one vote]]".<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.mainepublic.org/post/opposed-ranked-choice-voting-lepage-says-he-might-not-certify-primary-election-results |title=Opposed To Ranked-Choice Voting, LePage Says He Might Not Certify Primary Election Results |last=Leary |first=Mal |website=www.mainepublic.org |date=12 June 2018 |access-date=14 January 2019}}</ref> In litigation following the results of the [[Lucas St. Clair|2018 election for Maine's 2nd congressional district]], Representative Bruce Poliquin claimed that IRV allowed his opponents to "cast ballots for three different candidates in the same election".<ref>{{Cite Pacer |plaintiff=Baber |defendant=Dunlap |title=Complaint |date=13 November 2018 |case-division=1 |case-year=18 |case-type=cv |case-sequence=00465 |case-state=ME |doc-number=1 |recap-number=8169811 |access-date=13 January 2019}}</ref> Federal judge Lance Walker rejected this claim, and the 1st circuit court denied Poliquin's emergency appeal, leading to Poliquin dropping his claim.<ref>{{cite news |url=https://bangordailynews.com/2018/12/21/politics/1st-circuit-ends-poliquins-efforts-to-keep-house-seat/ |title=1st Circuit ends Poliquin's efforts to keep House seat |date=22 December 2018 |website=Bangor Daily News |access-date=17 August 2019}}</ref>
The same argument was advanced in opposition to IRV in Maine. Governor [[Paul LePage]] claimed, ahead of the 2018 primary elections, that IRV would result in "one person, five votes", as opposed to "[[one person, one vote]]".<ref>{{cite web |last=Leary |first=Mal |date=12 June 2018 |title=Opposed To Ranked-Choice Voting, LePage Says He Might Not Certify Primary Election Results |url=http://www.mainepublic.org/post/opposed-ranked-choice-voting-lepage-says-he-might-not-certify-primary-election-results |access-date=14 January 2019 |website=www.mainepublic.org}}</ref> In litigation following the results of the [[Lucas St. Clair|2018 election for Maine's 2nd congressional district]], Representative Bruce Poliquin claimed that IRV allowed his opponents to "cast ballots for three different candidates in the same election".<ref>{{Cite Pacer|plaintiff=Baber|defendant=Dunlap|title=Complaint|doc-number=1|date=13 November 2018|recap-number=8169811|case-state=ME|case-division=1|case-year=18|case-type=cv|case-sequence=00465|access-date=13 January 2019}}</ref> Federal judge Lance Walker rejected this claim, and the 1st circuit court denied Poliquin's emergency appeal, leading to Poliquin dropping his claim.<ref>{{cite news |date=22 December 2018 |title=1st Circuit ends Poliquin's efforts to keep House seat |url=https://bangordailynews.com/2018/12/21/politics/1st-circuit-ends-poliquins-efforts-to-keep-house-seat/ |access-date=17 August 2019 |website=Bangor Daily News}}</ref>


=== Similarity to plurality ===
=== Similarity to plurality ===
Because it is effectively a "repeated plurality" vote, results with instant-runoff voting are typically very similar to those under plurality, and instant-runoff behaves similarly to plurality. This has led many commentators and voting reform advocates to question whether IRV is worth the substantial additional costs and complexity needed to ultimately elect the same winner. For example, instant-runoff voting fails the [[Condorcet criterion]], meaning it fails to elect [[Median voter theorem|consensus winners]].
Because it is effectively a "repeated plurality" vote, results with instant-runoff voting are typically very similar to those under plurality, and instant-runoff behaves similarly to plurality. This has led many commentators and voting reform advocates to question whether IRV is worth the substantial additional costs and complexity needed to ultimately elect the same winner. For example, instant-runoff voting fails the [[Condorcet criterion]], meaning it fails to elect [[Median voter theorem|consensus winners]].


Most instant-runoff voting elections are won by the candidate who leads in first-choice rankings, choosing the same winner as [[plurality voting]]. In Australia, the [[1972 Australian federal election|1972 federal election]] had the highest proportion of winners who would not have won under first past the post—with only 14 out of 125 seats not won by the plurality candidate.<ref>{{Cite web |last=Green |first=Antony |date=11 May 2010 |title=Preferential Voting in Australia |url=https://www.abc.net.au/news/2010-05-12/preferential-voting-in-australia/9389472 |access-date=1 November 2020 |website=www.abc.net.au}}</ref>
Most instant-runoff voting elections are won by the candidate who leads in first-choice rankings, choosing the same winner as [[plurality voting]]. In Australia, the [[1972 Australian federal election|1972 federal election]] had the highest proportion of winners who would not have won under first past the post—with only 14 out of 125 seats not won by the plurality candidate.<ref>{{Cite web |last=Green |first=Antony |date=11 May 2010 |title=Preferential Voting in Australia |url=https://www.abc.net.au/news/2010-05-12/preferential-voting-in-australia/9389472 |access-date=1 November 2020 |website=www.abc.net.au}}</ref>


=== Participation ===
=== Participation ===
The effect of IRV on voter turnout is difficult to assess. In a lengthy 2021 report, researchers at [[New America (organization)|New America]], a [[think tank]] based in Washington, D. C., said:<ref name="auto1">{{Cite web |title=What We Know About Ranked-Choice Voting |url=http://newamerica.org/political-reform/reports/what-we-know-about-ranked-choice-voting/ |website=New America}}</ref>
The effect of IRV on voter turnout is difficult to assess. In a lengthy 2021 report, researchers at [[New America (organization)|New America]], a [[think tank]] based in Washington, D. C., said:<ref name="auto12">{{Cite web |title=What We Know About Ranked-Choice Voting |url=http://newamerica.org/political-reform/reports/what-we-know-about-ranked-choice-voting/ |website=New America}}</ref><blockquote>With our sample of cases largely limited to municipal and often nonpartisan elections (in relatively engaged localities), the best we can say for RCV [ranked-choice voting], independent of timing considerations, is that it may increase local turnout from a pathetic baseline to a slightly less pathetic level by attracting more, and more diverse, candidates. However, if RCV is able to combine the primary and the general election into a single election, held in November alongside other national elections, it is likely to have a more powerful effect in boosting turnout.</blockquote>The report concluded:<ref>{{cite news |last1=Drutman |first1=Lee |last2=Strano |first2=Maresa |date=10 November 2021 |title=What We Know About Ranked-Choice Voting |url=https://www.newamerica.org/political-reform/reports/what-we-know-about-ranked-choice-voting/conclusion/ |access-date=28 February 2023 |publisher=New America}}</ref><blockquote>And to the extent that RCV combines the primary and the general election into one, it increases turnout. However, many of the other hoped-for benefits, such as more diverse candidates (by gender, race, and ideology), higher turnout, and more viable parties, are harder to detect. Nor is there any evidence that RCV changes policy outcomes[...] In most elections, the candidate who would have won under plurality voting is also the candidate who won under ranked-choice voting.</blockquote>
<blockquote>With our sample of cases largely limited to municipal and often nonpartisan elections (in relatively engaged localities), the best we can say for RCV [ranked-choice voting], independent of timing considerations, is that it may increase local turnout from a pathetic baseline to a slightly less pathetic level by attracting more, and more diverse, candidates. However, if RCV is able to combine the primary and the general election into a single election, held in November alongside other national elections, it is likely to have a more powerful effect in boosting turnout.</blockquote>

The report concluded:<ref>{{cite news |last1=Drutman |first1=Lee |last2=Strano |first2=Maresa |title=What We Know About Ranked-Choice Voting |url=https://www.newamerica.org/political-reform/reports/what-we-know-about-ranked-choice-voting/conclusion/ |access-date=28 February 2023 |publisher=New America |date=10 November 2021}}</ref>
<blockquote> And to the extent that RCV combines the primary and the general election into one, it increases turnout. However, many of the other hoped-for benefits, such as more diverse candidates (by gender, race, and ideology), higher turnout, and more viable parties, are harder to detect. Nor is there any evidence that RCV changes policy outcomes[...] In most elections, the candidate who would have won under plurality voting is also the candidate who won under ranked-choice voting.</blockquote>


==History and use==
==History and use==
Line 128: Line 126:


=== History ===
=== History ===
This method was considered by [[Marquis de Condorcet|Condorcet]] as early as 1788, though only to condemn it for its ability to eliminate a candidate preferred by a majority of voters.<ref name=":03">{{Cite journal |last=Nanson |first=E. J. |date=1882 |title=Methods of election: Ware's Method |url=https://archive.org/details/transactionsproc1719roya/page/206 |journal=Transactions and Proceedings of the Royal Society of Victoria |volume=17 |pages=206 |quote=The method was, however, mentioned by Condorcet, but only to be condemned.}}</ref><ref>{{Cite book |last=Condorcet |first=Jean-Antoine-Nicolas de Caritat |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=d0cwAAAAYAAJ&q=Oeuvres%20de%20Condorcet,%20Volume%2013&pg=PA243 |title=On the Constitution and the Functions of Provincial Assemblies |date=1788 |work=Complete Works of Condorcet |volume=13 |publication-date=1804 |pages=243 |language=fr |quote=En effet, lorsqu'il y a plus de trois concurrents, le véritable vœu de la pluralité peut être pour un candidat qui n'ait eu aucune des voix dans le premier scrutin.}}</ref>
This method was considered by [[Marquis de Condorcet|Condorcet]] as early as 1788, though only to condemn it for its ability to eliminate a candidate preferred by a majority of voters.<ref name=":032">{{Cite journal |last=Nanson |first=E. J. |date=1882 |title=Methods of election: Ware's Method |url=https://archive.org/details/transactionsproc1719roya/page/206 |journal=Transactions and Proceedings of the Royal Society of Victoria |volume=17 |pages=206 |quote=The method was, however, mentioned by Condorcet, but only to be condemned.}}</ref><ref>{{Cite book |last=Condorcet |first=Jean-Antoine-Nicolas de Caritat |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=d0cwAAAAYAAJ&q=Oeuvres%20de%20Condorcet,%20Volume%2013&pg=PA243 |title=On the Constitution and the Functions of Provincial Assemblies |date=1788 |work=Complete Works of Condorcet |volume=13 |publication-date=1804 |pages=243 |language=fr |quote=En effet, lorsqu'il y a plus de trois concurrents, le véritable vœu de la pluralité peut être pour un candidat qui n'ait eu aucune des voix dans le premier scrutin.}}</ref>


IRV can be seen as a special case of the [[single transferable vote]] method, which [[Single transferable vote#History and current use|began use in the 1850s]]. It is historically known as '''Ware's method''', due to the implementation of STV in 1871 at [[Harvard College]] by American [[architect]] [[William Robert Ware]], who suggested it could also be used for single-winner elections.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Ware |first=William R. |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=W7QRAAAAYAAJ&pg=PA192 |title=Application of Mr. Hare's system of voting to the nomination of overseers of Harvard College. |date=1871 |oclc=81791186 |quote=It is equally efficient whether one candidate is to be chosen, or a dozen.}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |first=Benjamin |last=Reilly |title=The Global Spread of Preferential Voting: Australian Institutional Imperialism |url=http://archive.fairvote.org/articles/reilly.pdf |access-date=17 April 2011 |publisher=FairVote.org}}</ref> Ware noted that the vote counting took only two or three hours, less time than required to count votes in the previous university election when limited voting was used and each voter cast five votes.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Ware |first=William R. |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=W7QRAAAAYAAJ&pg=PA192 |title=Application of Mr. Hare's system of voting to the nomination of overseers of Harvard College. |date=1871 |oclc=81791186}}</ref> Unlike the single transferable vote in multi-seat elections, however, the only votes transferred are cast by backers of candidates who have been eliminated. There are no transfers of surplus votes as under STV.
IRV can be seen as a special case of the [[single transferable vote]] method, which [[Single transferable vote#History and current use|began use in the 1850s]]. It is historically known as '''Ware's method''', due to the implementation of STV in 1871 at [[Harvard College]] by American [[architect]] [[William Robert Ware]], who suggested it could also be used for single-winner elections.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Ware |first=William R. |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=W7QRAAAAYAAJ&pg=PA192 |title=Application of Mr. Hare's system of voting to the nomination of overseers of Harvard College. |date=1871 |oclc=81791186 |quote=It is equally efficient whether one candidate is to be chosen, or a dozen.}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |last=Reilly |first=Benjamin |title=The Global Spread of Preferential Voting: Australian Institutional Imperialism |url=http://archive.fairvote.org/articles/reilly.pdf |access-date=17 April 2011 |publisher=FairVote.org}}</ref> Ware noted that the vote counting took only two or three hours, less time than required to count votes in the previous university election when limited voting was used and each voter cast five votes.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Ware |first=William R. |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=W7QRAAAAYAAJ&pg=PA192 |title=Application of Mr. Hare's system of voting to the nomination of overseers of Harvard College. |date=1871 |oclc=81791186}}</ref> Unlike the single transferable vote in multi-seat elections, however, the only votes transferred are cast by backers of candidates who have been eliminated. There are no transfers of surplus votes as under STV.


The first known use of an IRV-like method in a governmental election was in the [[1893 Queensland colonial election|1893 general election]] in the [[Colony of Queensland]] (in present-day Australia).<ref>{{cite web |first=Iain |last=McLean |date=October 2002 |title=Australian electoral reform and two concepts of representation |url=http://www.nuffield.ox.ac.uk/Politics/papers/2002/w23/mclean.pdf |access-date=22 February 2008 |page=11}}</ref> The variant used for this election was a "[[contingent vote]]", where all candidates but two are eliminated in the first round, with one of the last two elected by majority after votes of the others are transferred. Queensland used contingent voting until 1942, one of the longest uses of the system anywhere.<ref>Bowler and Grofman, Elections in Australia, Ireland and Malta, p. 40</ref>
The first known use of an IRV-like method in a governmental election was in the [[1893 Queensland colonial election|1893 general election]] in the [[Colony of Queensland]] (in present-day Australia).<ref>{{cite web |last=McLean |first=Iain |date=October 2002 |title=Australian electoral reform and two concepts of representation |url=http://www.nuffield.ox.ac.uk/Politics/papers/2002/w23/mclean.pdf |access-date=22 February 2008 |page=11}}</ref> The variant used for this election was a "[[contingent vote]]", where all candidates but two are eliminated in the first round, with one of the last two elected by majority after votes of the others are transferred. Queensland used contingent voting until 1942, one of the longest uses of the system anywhere.<ref>Bowler and Grofman, Elections in Australia, Ireland and Malta, p. 40</ref>


IRV in its true form (what was called Alternative Voting at the time) was first used in [[Western Australia]], in the [[1908 Western Australian state election|1908 state election]]. To form up a majority behind one candidate, candidates are dropped one by one. The lower houses of all Australian states (except Tasmania and ACT) and the Australian House of Representatives are elected through IRV. The last state to adopt AV was Queensland in 1962, It had switched from contingent voting to single-member plurality in 1942.<ref>Farrell and McAllister, The Australian Electoral System, p. 50</ref> (Multi-winner STV of the [[Hare-Clark electoral system|Hare-Clark]] version was introduced for the [[Tasmanian House of Assembly]] at the [[1909 Tasmanian state election|1909 state election]]. ACT used modified d'Hondt (a party-list PR system) to 1995 when it adopted STV.)<ref>Farrell and McAllister, The Australian Electoral System, p. 72, 87</ref>
IRV in its true form (what was called Alternative Voting at the time) was first used in [[Western Australia]], in the [[1908 Western Australian state election|1908 state election]]. To form up a majority behind one candidate, candidates are dropped one by one. The lower houses of all Australian states (except Tasmania and ACT) and the Australian House of Representatives are elected through IRV. The last state to adopt AV was Queensland in 1962, It had switched from contingent voting to single-member plurality in 1942.<ref>Farrell and McAllister, The Australian Electoral System, p. 50</ref> (Multi-winner STV of the [[Hare-Clark electoral system|Hare-Clark]] version was introduced for the [[Tasmanian House of Assembly]] at the [[1909 Tasmanian state election|1909 state election]]. ACT used modified d'Hondt (a party-list PR system) to 1995 when it adopted STV.)<ref>Farrell and McAllister, The Australian Electoral System, p. 72, 87</ref>


IRV was introduced for federal (nationwide) elections in Australia after the [[1918 Swan by-election|Swan by-election]] in October 1918, in response to the rise of the conservative [[National Party of Australia|Country Party]], representing small farmers. The Country Party split the non-[[Australian Labor Party|Labor]] vote in conservative country areas, allowing Labor candidates to win without a majority of the vote. The conservative government of [[Billy Hughes]] introduced IRV (in Australia called "preferential voting") as a means of allowing competition between the [[Coalition (Australia)|Coalition]] parties without putting seats at risk. It was first used at the [[1918 Corangamite by-election|Corangamite by-election]] on 14 December 1918, and at a national level at the [[1919 Australian federal election|1919 election]].<ref>{{cite web |title=Australian Electoral History: Voting Methods |url=http://australianpolitics.com/elections/features/voting-methods-history.shtml |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110319034900/http://australianpolitics.com/elections/features/voting-methods-history.shtml |archive-date=19 March 2011 |access-date=17 April 2011 |publisher=Australianpolitics.com}}</ref> IRV continued to benefit the Coalition until the [[1990 Australian federal election|1990 election]], when for the first time Labor obtained a net benefit from IRV.<ref>{{cite news |date=22 September 2015 |title=The Origin of Senate Group Ticket Voting, and it didn't come from the Major Parties |newspaper=ABC News |url=http://www.abc.net.au/news/2015-09-23/the-origin-of-senate-group-ticket-voting-and-it-didnt-come-from-/9388658}}</ref>
IRV was introduced for federal (nationwide) elections in Australia after the [[1918 Swan by-election|Swan by-election]] in October 1918, in response to the rise of the conservative [[National Party of Australia|Country Party]], representing small farmers. The Country Party split the non-[[Australian Labor Party|Labor]] vote in conservative country areas, allowing Labor candidates to win without a majority of the vote. The conservative government of [[Billy Hughes]] introduced IRV (in Australia called "preferential voting") as a means of allowing competition between the [[Coalition (Australia)|Coalition]] parties without putting seats at risk. It was first used at the [[1918 Corangamite by-election|Corangamite by-election]] on 14 December 1918, and at a national level at the [[1919 Australian federal election|1919 election]].<ref>{{cite web |title=Australian Electoral History: Voting Methods |url=http://australianpolitics.com/elections/features/voting-methods-history.shtml |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110319034900/http://australianpolitics.com/elections/features/voting-methods-history.shtml |archive-date=19 March 2011 |access-date=17 April 2011 |publisher=Australianpolitics.com}}</ref> IRV continued to benefit the Coalition until the [[1990 Australian federal election|1990 election]], when for the first time Labor obtained a net benefit from IRV.<ref>{{cite news |date=22 September 2015 |title=The Origin of Senate Group Ticket Voting, and it didn't come from the Major Parties |url=http://www.abc.net.au/news/2015-09-23/the-origin-of-senate-group-ticket-voting-and-it-didnt-come-from-/9388658 |newspaper=ABC News}}</ref>


In 1990, for example, the small Baltic state of Estonia held its first post-Soviet elections under a combination of IRV and STV — a system which had been popularized by Rein Taagepera, an expatriate Estonian political scientist from the University of California.<ref name="auto">https://archive.fairvote.org/articles/reilly.pdf</ref>
In 1990, for example, the small Baltic state of Estonia held its first post-Soviet elections under a combination of IRV and STV — a system which had been popularized by Rein Taagepera, an expatriate Estonian political scientist from the University of California.<ref name="auto2">https://archive.fairvote.org/articles/reilly.pdf</ref>


In 2000, Bosnia used IRV for its election.<ref name="auto" />
In 2000, Bosnia used IRV for its election.<ref name="auto2" />


=== Global use ===
=== Global use ===
Line 146: Line 144:


==== National level elections ====
==== National level elections ====
{| class="wikitable sortable" cellspacing="0" cellpadding="2" border="1" style="indonesmargin: 1em 1em 1em 0; background: #f9f9f9; border: 1px #aaa solid; border-collapse: collapse; font-size: 95%;"
{| class="wikitable sortable" border="1" cellpadding="2" cellspacing="0"
! scope="col" |Country
! scope="col" |Country
! scope="col" |Body or office
! scope="col" |Body or office
Line 171: Line 169:
|Lower chamber of legislature
|Lower chamber of legislature
|[[Single transferable vote]] (STV), by-elections using IRV
|[[Single transferable vote]] (STV), by-elections using IRV
|158<ref name="fn_2">The [[Ceann Comhairle]] or Speaker of [[Dáil Éireann]] is returned automatically for whichever constituency s/he was elected if they wish to seek re-election, reducing the number of seats contested in that constituency by one. (In that case, should the Ceann Comhairle be from a three-seater, only two seats are contested in the general election from there.) As a result, if the Ceann Comhairle wishes to be in the next Dáil, only 165 seats are actually contested in a general election.</ref>
|158<ref name="fn_22">The [[Ceann Comhairle]] or Speaker of [[Dáil Éireann]] is returned automatically for whichever constituency s/he was elected if they wish to seek re-election, reducing the number of seats contested in that constituency by one. (In that case, should the Ceann Comhairle be from a three-seater, only two seats are contested in the general election from there.) As a result, if the Ceann Comhairle wishes to be in the next Dáil, only 165 seats are actually contested in a general election.</ref>
|
|
|-
|-
Line 184: Line 182:
|[[President of the United States|President]] (via [[United States Electoral College|Electoral College]])
|[[President of the United States|President]] (via [[United States Electoral College|Electoral College]])
|Head of State and Government
|Head of State and Government
|[[Alaska]] and [[Maine]] use IRV to select the state winner. In Maine, 2 electors are allocated to the winner and the others (currently 2) are allocated by congressional district, while in Alaska, the winner gets all electors of the state in the Electoral College system (as Alaska has only one ''at-large'' district, the effect is the same).
|[[Alaska]] and [[Maine]] use IRV to select the state winner. In Maine, 2 electors are allocated to the winner and the others (currently 2) are allocated by congressional district, while in Alaska, the winner gets all electors of the state in the Electoral College system (as Alaska has only one ''at-large'' district, the effect is the same).
|7 EVs<ref>electoral votes</ref> (out of 538)
|7 EVs<ref>electoral votes</ref> (out of 538)
|
|
Line 191: Line 189:
|Lower chamber of legislature
|Lower chamber of legislature
| rowspan="2" |IRV in Maine
| rowspan="2" |IRV in Maine
Nonpartisan primary system with IRV in the second round (among top four candidates) in Alaska.<ref name="boston.com">{{cite web |date=10 November 2016 |title=Maine became the first state in the country Tuesday to pass ranked choice voting |url=https://www.boston.com/news/politics/2016/11/10/maine-became-the-first-state-in-the-country-to-pass-ranked-choice-voting |access-date=10 November 2016}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web |title=Ranked Choice Voting {{!}} Maine Voters Rank Candidates |url=http://mainerankedchoice.vote |access-date=8 April 2018 |website=Maine Uses Ranked Choice Voting}}</ref><ref name="Maine2018">{{cite news |first=Eric |last=Russell |date=12 June 2018 |title=Mainers vote to keep ranked-choice voting, with supporters holding commanding lead |publisher=Portland Press Herald |url=https://www.pressherald.com/2018/06/12/ranked-choice-voting-takes-lead-in-early-balloting/ |access-date=13 June 2018}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web |title=Alaska Ballot Measure 2, Top-Four Ranked-Choice Voting and Campaign Finance Laws Initiative (2020) |url=https://ballotpedia.org/Alaska_Ballot_Measure_2,_Top-Four_Ranked-Choice_Voting_and_Campaign_Finance_Laws_Initiative_(2020) |access-date=17 November 2020 |website=Ballotpedia}}</ref>
Nonpartisan primary system with IRV in the second round (among top four candidates) in Alaska.<ref name="boston.com2">{{cite web |date=10 November 2016 |title=Maine became the first state in the country Tuesday to pass ranked choice voting |url=https://www.boston.com/news/politics/2016/11/10/maine-became-the-first-state-in-the-country-to-pass-ranked-choice-voting |access-date=10 November 2016}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web |title=Ranked Choice Voting {{!}} Maine Voters Rank Candidates |url=http://mainerankedchoice.vote |access-date=8 April 2018 |website=Maine Uses Ranked Choice Voting}}</ref><ref name="Maine20182">{{cite news |last=Russell |first=Eric |date=12 June 2018 |title=Mainers vote to keep ranked-choice voting, with supporters holding commanding lead |url=https://www.pressherald.com/2018/06/12/ranked-choice-voting-takes-lead-in-early-balloting/ |access-date=13 June 2018 |publisher=Portland Press Herald}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web |title=Alaska Ballot Measure 2, Top-Four Ranked-Choice Voting and Campaign Finance Laws Initiative (2020) |url=https://ballotpedia.org/Alaska_Ballot_Measure_2,_Top-Four_Ranked-Choice_Voting_and_Campaign_Finance_Laws_Initiative_(2020) |access-date=17 November 2020 |website=Ballotpedia}}</ref>
|3 (out of 435)
|3 (out of 435)
|
|
Line 202: Line 200:


=== ''Robert's Rules of Order'' ===
=== ''Robert's Rules of Order'' ===
In the United States, the sequential elimination method used by IRV is described in ''[[Robert's Rules of Order|Robert's Rules of Order Newly Revised]]'' as an example of [[Ranked voting systems|ranked-choice voting]] that can be used to elect officers.<ref name="autogenerated12" /> ''Robert's Rules'' note that ranked-choice systems (including IRV) are an improvement on [[Plurality voting|simple plurality]] but recommend against runoff-based rules because they often prevent the emergence of a consensus candidate with broad support. The book instead recommends repeated balloting until some candidate manages to win a majority of votes. Two other books on American parliamentary procedure, ''[[The Standard Code of Parliamentary Procedure]]''<ref>{{cite parl|title=TSC|page=148|edition=4th}}</ref> and ''[[Riddick's Rules of Procedure]]'',<ref>{{cite parl|title=RID|page=145|edition=1985|year=1985}}</ref> take a similar stance.

In the United States, the sequential elimination method used by IRV is described in ''[[Robert's Rules of Order|Robert's Rules of Order Newly Revised]]'' as an example of [[Ranked voting systems|ranked-choice voting]] that can be used to elect officers.<ref name="autogenerated1" /> ''Robert's Rules'' note that ranked-choice systems (including IRV) are an improvement on [[Plurality voting|simple plurality]] but recommend against runoff-based rules because they often prevent the emergence of a consensus candidate with broad support. The book instead recommends repeated balloting until some candidate manages to win a majority of votes. Two other books on American parliamentary procedure, ''[[The Standard Code of Parliamentary Procedure]]''<ref>{{cite parl|title=TSC|page=148|edition=4th}}</ref> and ''[[Riddick's Rules of Procedure]]'',<ref>{{cite parl|title=RID|page=145|edition=1985|year=1985}}</ref> take a similar stance.


==Similar methods==
==Similar methods==

===Runoff voting===
===Runoff voting===
The term ''instant runoff voting'' is derived from the name of a class of voting methods called runoff voting. In runoff voting voters do not rank candidates in order of preference on a single ballot. Instead a similar effect is achieved by using multiple rounds of voting. All multi-round runoff voting methods allow voters to change their preferences in each round, incorporating the results of the prior round to influence their decision, which is not possible in IRV.
The term ''instant runoff voting'' is derived from the name of a class of voting methods called runoff voting. In runoff voting voters do not rank candidates in order of preference on a single ballot. Instead a similar effect is achieved by using multiple rounds of voting. All multi-round runoff voting methods allow voters to change their preferences in each round, incorporating the results of the prior round to influence their decision, which is not possible in IRV.


The runoff method closest to IRV is the [[exhaustive ballot]]. In this method—familiar to fans of the television show ''[[American Idol]]''—one candidate is eliminated after each round, and many rounds of voting are used, rather than just two.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.securevote.com.au/gloss_of_terms.html#e |title=Glossary: Exhaustive ballot |publisher=Securevote.com.au |access-date=6 May 2010}}</ref> Because holding many rounds of voting on separate days is generally expensive, the exhaustive ballot is not used for large-scale, public elections.
The runoff method closest to IRV is the [[exhaustive ballot]]. In this method—familiar to fans of the television show ''[[American Idol]]''—one candidate is eliminated after each round, and many rounds of voting are used, rather than just two.<ref>{{cite web |title=Glossary: Exhaustive ballot |url=http://www.securevote.com.au/gloss_of_terms.html#e |access-date=6 May 2010 |publisher=Securevote.com.au}}</ref> Because holding many rounds of voting on separate days is generally expensive, the exhaustive ballot is not used for large-scale, public elections.


A more practical form of runoff voting is the [[two-round system]], which excludes all but the top-two candidates after the first round, rather than gradually eliminating candidates over a series of rounds. Eliminations can occur with or without allowing and applying preference votes to choose the final two candidates. A second round of voting or counting is only necessary if no candidate receives an overall majority of votes. This method is used in Mali, France and the Finnish and Slovenian presidential election.
A more practical form of runoff voting is the [[two-round system]], which excludes all but the top-two candidates after the first round, rather than gradually eliminating candidates over a series of rounds. Eliminations can occur with or without allowing and applying preference votes to choose the final two candidates. A second round of voting or counting is only necessary if no candidate receives an overall majority of votes. This method is used in Mali, France and the Finnish and Slovenian presidential election.


===Contingent vote===
===Contingent vote===
[[File:IRV-toptwo flowchart.png|thumb|Top-two IRV]]
[[File:IRV-toptwo_flowchart.png|thumb|Top-two IRV]]
The [[contingent vote]], also known as "top-two IRV" or the "supplementary vote", is the same as IRV, except that if no candidate achieves a majority in the first round of counting, all but the two candidates with the most votes are eliminated, and the second preferences for those ballots are counted. As in IRV, there is only one round of voting.
The [[contingent vote]], also known as "top-two IRV" or the "supplementary vote", is the same as IRV, except that if no candidate achieves a majority in the first round of counting, all but the two candidates with the most votes are eliminated, and the second preferences for those ballots are counted. As in IRV, there is only one round of voting.


Under a variant of contingent voting used in [[Sri Lanka]], and the elections for [[Mayor of London]] in the United Kingdom, voters rank a specified maximum number of candidates. In London, the supplementary vote allows voters to express first and second preferences only. Sri Lankan voters [[Contingent vote#contingent vote in Sri Lanka|rank up to three candidates to elect the president of Sri Lanka]].
Under a variant of contingent voting used in [[Sri Lanka]], and the elections for [[Mayor of London]] in the United Kingdom, voters rank a specified maximum number of candidates. In London, the supplementary vote allows voters to express first and second preferences only. Sri Lankan voters [[Contingent vote#contingent vote in Sri Lanka|rank up to three candidates to elect the president of Sri Lanka]].


While similar to "sequential-elimination" IRV, top-two can produce different results. Excluding more than one candidate after the first count might eliminate a candidate who would have won under sequential elimination IRV. Restricting voters to a maximum number of preferences is more likely to exhaust ballots if voters do not anticipate which candidates will finish in the top two. This can encourage voters to vote more [[tactical voting|tactically]], by ranking at least one candidate they think is likely to win.
While similar to "sequential-elimination" IRV, top-two can produce different results. Excluding more than one candidate after the first count might eliminate a candidate who would have won under sequential elimination IRV. Restricting voters to a maximum number of preferences is more likely to exhaust ballots if voters do not anticipate which candidates will finish in the top two. This can encourage voters to vote more [[Tactical voting|tactically]], by ranking at least one candidate they think is likely to win.


Conversely, a practical benefit of 'contingent voting' is expediency and confidence in the result with only two rounds.
Conversely, a practical benefit of 'contingent voting' is expediency and confidence in the result with only two rounds.
Line 226: Line 222:
===Larger runoff process===
===Larger runoff process===
IRV may also be part of a larger runoff process:
IRV may also be part of a larger runoff process:

* Some jurisdictions that hold runoff elections allow absentee (only) voters to submit IRV ballots, because the interval between votes is too short for a second round of absentee voting. IRV ballots enable absentee votes to count in the second (general) election round if their first choice does not make the runoff. [[Arkansas]], [[South Carolina]] and [[Springfield, Illinois]] adopt this approach.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.electionline.org/Portals/1/Publications/SC.EAP.2006primary.pdf |title=Initiatives – Pew Center on the States |publisher=Electionline.org |access-date=6 May 2010 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080516235221/http://www.electionline.org/Portals/1/Publications/SC.EAP.2006primary.pdf |archive-date=16 May 2008}}</ref> Louisiana uses it only for members of the United States Service or who reside overseas.<ref>{{Citation |title=IRV for Louisiana's Overseas Voters |type=web page |publisher=FairVote IRV America |url=http://archive.fairvote.org/?page=1669 |access-date=16 June 2013}}</ref>
* Some jurisdictions that hold runoff elections allow absentee (only) voters to submit IRV ballots, because the interval between votes is too short for a second round of absentee voting. IRV ballots enable absentee votes to count in the second (general) election round if their first choice does not make the runoff. [[Arkansas]], [[South Carolina]] and [[Springfield, Illinois]] adopt this approach.<ref>{{cite web |title=Initiatives – Pew Center on the States |url=http://www.electionline.org/Portals/1/Publications/SC.EAP.2006primary.pdf |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080516235221/http://www.electionline.org/Portals/1/Publications/SC.EAP.2006primary.pdf |archive-date=16 May 2008 |access-date=6 May 2010 |publisher=Electionline.org}}</ref> Louisiana uses it only for members of the United States Service or who reside overseas.<ref>{{Citation |title=IRV for Louisiana's Overseas Voters |type=web page |url=http://archive.fairvote.org/?page=1669 |access-date=16 June 2013 |publisher=FairVote IRV America}}</ref>
* IRV can quickly eliminate weak candidates in early rounds of an [[exhaustive ballot]] runoff, using rules to leave the desired number of candidates for further balloting.
* IRV can quickly eliminate weak candidates in early rounds of an [[exhaustive ballot]] runoff, using rules to leave the desired number of candidates for further balloting.
* IRV elections that require a majority of cast ballots but not that voters rank all candidates may require more than a single IRV ballot due to exhausted ballots.
* IRV elections that require a majority of cast ballots but not that voters rank all candidates may require more than a single IRV ballot due to exhausted ballots.
* Robert's Rules recommends [[Ranked voting systems|preferential voting]] for elections by mail and requiring a majority of cast votes to elect a winner. For in-person elections, they recommend repeated balloting until one candidate receives an absolute majority of all votes cast; if candidates drop out as soon as it becomes clear they cannot win, this procedure will always elect a [[Condorcet method|Condorcet winner]]. The use of repeated balloting allows voters to resolve [[Condorcet cycle|Condorcet cycles]] by discussion and compromise, or by electing a consensus candidate who might have polled poorly in the initial election.<ref name="autogenerated1" />
* Robert's Rules recommends [[Ranked voting systems|preferential voting]] for elections by mail and requiring a majority of cast votes to elect a winner. For in-person elections, they recommend repeated balloting until one candidate receives an absolute majority of all votes cast; if candidates drop out as soon as it becomes clear they cannot win, this procedure will always elect a [[Condorcet method|Condorcet winner]]. The use of repeated balloting allows voters to resolve [[Condorcet cycle|Condorcet cycles]] by discussion and compromise, or by electing a consensus candidate who might have polled poorly in the initial election.<ref name="autogenerated12" />


===Comparison to first-past-the-post===
===Comparison to first-past-the-post===
Line 238: Line 235:
A number of IRV methods, varying as to ballot design and as to whether or not voters are obliged to provide a full list of preferences, are in use in different countries and local governments.
A number of IRV methods, varying as to ballot design and as to whether or not voters are obliged to provide a full list of preferences, are in use in different countries and local governments.


In an [[optional preferential voting]] system, voters can give a preference to as many candidates as they wish. They may make only a single choice, known as "[[bullet voting]]", and some jurisdictions accept a single box marked with an "X" (as opposed to a numeral "1") as valid for the first preference. This may result in exhausted ballots, where all of a voter's preferences are eliminated before a candidate is elected, such that the "majority" in the final round may only constitute a minority fraction of all ballots cast. Optional preferential voting is used for elections for the [[President of Ireland]] as well as some elections in [[New South Wales]] and [[Queensland]].<ref>{{cite web |publisher=Electoral Commission of Queensland |date=28 January 2020 |title=Voting system |url=https://www.ecq.qld.gov.au/how-to-vote/voting-systems |access-date=17 November 2020 |website=www.ecq.qld.gov.au}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |last1=Stevens |first1=Bronwyn |title=Are Queenslanders in danger of 'wasting' their votes? |url=https://www.theconversation.com/amp/are-queenslanders-in-danger-of-wasting-their-votes-35919 |access-date=28 November 2020 |website=The Conversation |date=27 January 2015}}</ref>
In an [[optional preferential voting]] system, voters can give a preference to as many candidates as they wish. They may make only a single choice, known as "[[bullet voting]]", and some jurisdictions accept a single box marked with an "X" (as opposed to a numeral "1") as valid for the first preference. This may result in exhausted ballots, where all of a voter's preferences are eliminated before a candidate is elected, such that the "majority" in the final round may only constitute a minority fraction of all ballots cast. Optional preferential voting is used for elections for the [[President of Ireland]] as well as some elections in [[New South Wales]] and [[Queensland]].<ref>{{cite web |date=28 January 2020 |title=Voting system |url=https://www.ecq.qld.gov.au/how-to-vote/voting-systems |access-date=17 November 2020 |website=www.ecq.qld.gov.au |publisher=Electoral Commission of Queensland}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |last1=Stevens |first1=Bronwyn |date=27 January 2015 |title=Are Queenslanders in danger of 'wasting' their votes? |url=https://www.theconversation.com/amp/are-queenslanders-in-danger-of-wasting-their-votes-35919 |access-date=28 November 2020 |website=The Conversation}}</ref>


In a full-preferential voting method, voters are required to mark a preference for every candidate standing.<ref>{{cite web |title=Electoral Systems |url=http://www.eca.gov.au/systems/single/by_category/preferential.htm |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080309220219/http://www.eca.gov.au/systems/single/by_category/preferential.htm |archive-date=9 March 2008 |access-date=15 February 2008 |publisher=Electoral Council of Australia}}</ref> Ballots that do not contain a complete ordering of all candidates are in some jurisdictions considered [[spoilt vote|spoilt]] or invalid, even if there are only two candidates standing. This can become burdensome in elections with many candidates and can lead to "[[donkey voting]]", in which some voters simply choose candidates at random or in top-to-bottom order, or a voter may order his or her preferred candidates and then fill in the remainder on a donkey basis. Full preferential voting is used for elections to the [[Australian electoral system|Australian federal parliament]] and for most [[Electoral systems of the Australian states and territories|state parliaments]].
In a full-preferential voting method, voters are required to mark a preference for every candidate standing.<ref>{{cite web |title=Electoral Systems |url=http://www.eca.gov.au/systems/single/by_category/preferential.htm |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080309220219/http://www.eca.gov.au/systems/single/by_category/preferential.htm |archive-date=9 March 2008 |access-date=15 February 2008 |publisher=Electoral Council of Australia}}</ref> Ballots that do not contain a complete ordering of all candidates are in some jurisdictions considered [[Spoilt vote|spoilt]] or invalid, even if there are only two candidates standing. This can become burdensome in elections with many candidates and can lead to "[[donkey voting]]", in which some voters simply choose candidates at random or in top-to-bottom order, or a voter may order his or her preferred candidates and then fill in the remainder on a donkey basis. Full preferential voting is used for elections to the [[Australian electoral system|Australian federal parliament]] and for most [[Electoral systems of the Australian states and territories|state parliaments]].


Other methods only allow marking preferences for a maximum of the voter's top three favourites, a form of partial preferential voting.<ref>{{cite web |title=Ranked-Choice Voting |url=http://www.acgov.org/rov/rcv/faq.htm |access-date=15 December 2016 |website=Registrar of Voters, Alameda County |quote=This format allows a voter to select a first-choice candidate in the first column, a second-choice candidate in the second column, and a third-choice candidate in the third column.}}</ref>
Other methods only allow marking preferences for a maximum of the voter's top three favourites, a form of partial preferential voting.<ref>{{cite web |title=Ranked-Choice Voting |url=http://www.acgov.org/rov/rcv/faq.htm |access-date=15 December 2016 |website=Registrar of Voters, Alameda County |quote=This format allows a voter to select a first-choice candidate in the first column, a second-choice candidate in the second column, and a third-choice candidate in the third column.}}</ref>


A version of instant-runoff voting applying to the ranking of parties was first proposed for elections in Germany in 2013<ref>{{cite report |last1=Breyer |first1=Patrick |title=Anhörung zum Entwurf eines Gesetzes zur Abschaffung der Fünf-Prozent-Sperrklausel bei Landtagswahlen in Schleswig-Holstein |date=November 2013 |publisher=Piratenfraktion im Schleswig-Holsteinischen Landtag |chapter=Alternative II: Einführung einer Ersatzstimme |chapter-url=https://www.landtag.ltsh.de/infothek/wahl18/umdrucke/1900/umdruck-18-1916.pdf |language=de |trans-title=Hearing on the draft law to abolish the five percent threshold in state elections in Schleswig-Holstein (Discussion paper) |id=(Drs. 18/385)}}</ref> as [[spare vote]].<ref>{{Cite web |url=http://www.dualvoting.com/ |title=Dual Level Voting - Granting equal votes in a proportional election with a threshold |website=www.dualvoting.com}}</ref>
A version of instant-runoff voting applying to the ranking of parties was first proposed for elections in Germany in 2013<ref>{{cite report |title=Anhörung zum Entwurf eines Gesetzes zur Abschaffung der Fünf-Prozent-Sperrklausel bei Landtagswahlen in Schleswig-Holstein |trans-title=Hearing on the draft law to abolish the five percent threshold in state elections in Schleswig-Holstein (Discussion paper) |last1=Breyer |first1=Patrick |date=November 2013 |publisher=Piratenfraktion im Schleswig-Holsteinischen Landtag |language=de |id=(Drs. 18/385) |chapter=Alternative II: Einführung einer Ersatzstimme |chapter-url=https://www.landtag.ltsh.de/infothek/wahl18/umdrucke/1900/umdruck-18-1916.pdf}}</ref> as [[spare vote]].<ref>{{Cite web |title=Dual Level Voting - Granting equal votes in a proportional election with a threshold |url=http://www.dualvoting.com/ |website=www.dualvoting.com}}</ref>


== Voting method criteria ==
== Voting method criteria ==
Scholars rate voting methods using mathematically derived [[Comparison of electoral systems#Mathematical criteria|voting method criteria]], which describe desirable features of a method. No ranked-preference method can meet all of the criteria, because some of them are mutually exclusive, as shown by statements such as [[Arrow's impossibility theorem]] and the [[Gibbard–Satterthwaite theorem]].
Scholars rate voting methods using mathematically derived [[Comparison of electoral systems#Mathematical criteria|voting method criteria]], which describe desirable features of a method. No ranked-preference method can meet all of the criteria, because some of them are mutually exclusive, as shown by statements such as [[Arrow's impossibility theorem]] and the [[Gibbard–Satterthwaite theorem]].


Many of the mathematical criteria by which voting methods are compared were formulated for voters with ordinal preferences. If voters vote according to the same ordinal preferences in both rounds, criteria can be applied to [[two-round system]]s of runoffs, and in that case, each of the criteria failed by IRV is also failed by the [[two-round system]] as they relate to automatic elimination of trailing candidates. Partial results exist for other models of voter behavior in the two-round method: see the [[Two-round system#Compliance with voting method criteria|two-round system article's criterion compliance section]] for more information.
Many of the mathematical criteria by which voting methods are compared were formulated for voters with ordinal preferences. If voters vote according to the same ordinal preferences in both rounds, criteria can be applied to [[Two-round system|two-round systems]] of runoffs, and in that case, each of the criteria failed by IRV is also failed by the [[two-round system]] as they relate to automatic elimination of trailing candidates. Partial results exist for other models of voter behavior in the two-round method: see the [[Two-round system#Compliance with voting method criteria|two-round system article's criterion compliance section]] for more information.


=== Satisfied criteria ===
=== Satisfied criteria ===
The [[Condorcet loser criterion|Condorcet loser]] criterion states that "if a candidate would lose a [[Condorcet method|head-to-head competition]] against every other candidate, then that candidate must not win the overall election". IRV (like all voting methods with a final runoff round) meets this criterion, since the Condorcet loser cannot win a runoff, however IRV can still elect the "second-worst" candidate, when the two worst candidates are the only ones remaining in the final round.<ref name=":02">{{Cite journal |last=Nanson |first=E. J. |date=1882 |title=Methods of election |url=https://archive.org/details/transactionsproc1719roya/page/207 |journal=Transactions and Proceedings of the Royal Society of Victoria |volume=19 |pages=207–208 |quote=although Ware's method cannot return the worst, it may return the next worst.}}</ref>
The [[Condorcet loser criterion|Condorcet loser]] criterion states that "if a candidate would lose a [[Condorcet method|head-to-head competition]] against every other candidate, then that candidate must not win the overall election." IRV (like all voting methods with a final runoff round) meets this criterion, since the Condorcet loser cannot win a runoff, however IRV can still elect the "second-worst" candidate, when the two worst candidates are the only ones remaining in the final round.<ref name=":022">{{Cite journal |last=Nanson |first=E. J. |date=1882 |title=Methods of election |url=https://archive.org/details/transactionsproc1719roya/page/207 |journal=Transactions and Proceedings of the Royal Society of Victoria |volume=19 |pages=207–208 |quote=although Ware's method cannot return the worst, it may return the next worst.}}</ref>


The [[independence of clones criterion]] states that "the election outcome remains the same even if an identical candidate who is equally preferred decides to run". IRV meets this criterion.<ref>{{cite web |last1=Green-Armytage |first1=James |title=A Survey of Basic Voting Methods |url=http://www.econ.ucsb.edu/~armytage/voting/survey.htm |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130603015026/http://www.econ.ucsb.edu/~armytage/voting/survey.htm |archive-date=3 June 2013 |date=2004}}</ref> The [[later-no-harm criterion|later-no-harm]] criterion states that "if a voter alters the order of candidates lower in his/her preference (e.g. swapping the second and third preferences), then that does not affect the chances of the most preferred candidate being elected".
The [[independence of clones criterion]] states that "the election outcome remains the same even if an identical candidate who is equally preferred decides to run". IRV meets this criterion.<ref>{{cite web |last1=Green-Armytage |first1=James |date=2004 |title=A Survey of Basic Voting Methods |url=http://www.econ.ucsb.edu/~armytage/voting/survey.htm |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130603015026/http://www.econ.ucsb.edu/~armytage/voting/survey.htm |archive-date=3 June 2013}}</ref> The [[Later-no-harm criterion|later-no-harm]] criterion states that "if a voter alters the order of candidates lower in his/her preference (e.g. swapping the second and third preferences), then that does not affect the chances of the most preferred candidate being elected".


The [[majority criterion]] states that "if one candidate is preferred by an absolute majority of voters, then that candidate must win". The [[mutual majority criterion|mutual majority]] criterion states that "if an absolute majority of voters prefer every member of a group of candidates to every candidate not in that group, then one of the preferred group must win". Note that this is satisfied because when all but one candidate that a mutual majority prefer is eliminated, the votes of the majority all flow to the remaining candidate, in contrast to [[FPTP]], where the majority would be treated as separate small groups. The [[resolvability criterion|resolvability]] criterion states that "the probability of an exact tie must diminish as more votes are cast".
The [[majority criterion]] states that "if one candidate is preferred by an absolute majority of voters, then that candidate must win". The [[Mutual majority criterion|mutual majority]] criterion states that "if an absolute majority of voters prefer every member of a group of candidates to every candidate not in that group, then one of the preferred group must win". Note that this is satisfied because when all but one candidate that a mutual majority prefer is eliminated, the votes of the majority all flow to the remaining candidate, in contrast to [[FPTP]], where the majority would be treated as separate small groups. The [[Resolvability criterion|resolvability]] criterion states that "the probability of an exact tie must diminish as more votes are cast".


=== Pathologies of IRV ===
=== Pathologies of IRV ===

==== Spoiler effects ====
==== Spoiler effects ====
Instant-runoff voting is vulnerable to spoiler effects, as it violates [[independence of irrelevant alternatives]] (see below). In the general case, instant-runoff voting can be susceptible to [[strategic nomination]]: whether or not a candidate decides to run at all can affect the result even if the new candidate cannot themselves win.<ref name="wds2">{{cite web |title=Burlington Vermont 2009 IRV mayoral election |url=http://rangevoting.org/Burlington.html |access-date=17 April 2011 |publisher=RangeVoting.org}}</ref> This is less likely than under [[plurality voting]]

Instant-runoff voting is vulnerable to spoiler effects, as it violates [[independence of irrelevant alternatives]] (see below). In the general case, instant-runoff voting can be susceptible to [[strategic nomination]]: whether or not a candidate decides to run at all can affect the result even if the new candidate cannot themselves win.<ref name="wds" /> This is less likely than under [[plurality voting]]


==== Condorcet winner criterion ====
==== Condorcet winner criterion ====

The [[Condorcet criterion|Condorcet winner]] criterion states that "if a candidate would win a [[Condorcet method|head-to-head competition]] against every other candidate, then that candidate must win the overall election". It is incompatible with the later-no-harm criterion, so IRV does not meet this criterion.
The [[Condorcet criterion|Condorcet winner]] criterion states that "if a candidate would win a [[Condorcet method|head-to-head competition]] against every other candidate, then that candidate must win the overall election". It is incompatible with the later-no-harm criterion, so IRV does not meet this criterion.


IRV is more likely to elect the Condorcet winner than [[plurality voting]] and [[Two-round system|traditional runoff]] elections. The California cities of Oakland, San Francisco and San Leandro in 2010 provide an example; there were a total of four elections in which the plurality-voting leader in first-choice rankings was defeated, and in each case the IRV winner was the Condorcet winner, including a San Francisco election in which the IRV winner was in third place in first choice rankings.<ref>{{cite web |author=FairVote |url=http://www.fairvote.org/understanding-the-rcv-election-results-d10 |title=Understanding the RCV Election Results in District 10 |publisher=FairVote.org |access-date=17 April 2011 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110726045123/http://www.fairvote.org/understanding-the-rcv-election-results-d10 |archive-date=26 July 2011}}</ref>
IRV is more likely to elect the Condorcet winner than [[plurality voting]] and [[Two-round system|traditional runoff]] elections. The California cities of Oakland, San Francisco and San Leandro in 2010 provide an example; there were a total of four elections in which the plurality-voting leader in first-choice rankings was defeated, and in each case the IRV winner was the Condorcet winner, including a San Francisco election in which the IRV winner was in third place in first choice rankings.<ref>{{cite web |author=FairVote |title=Understanding the RCV Election Results in District 10 |url=http://www.fairvote.org/understanding-the-rcv-election-results-d10 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110726045123/http://www.fairvote.org/understanding-the-rcv-election-results-d10 |archive-date=26 July 2011 |access-date=17 April 2011 |publisher=FairVote.org}}</ref>


Systems which fail Condorcet but pass [[Mutual majority criterion|mutual majority]] can exclude voters outside the mutual majority from the vote, essentially becoming an election between the mutual majority.{{citation needed|date=November 2020}} IRV demonstrates this exclusion of up to 50 percent of voters, notably in the [[2009 Burlington mayoral election]] where the later rounds became a runoff between the mutual majority of voters favouring Andy Montroll and Bob Kiss. This can [[recursion|recurse]]: if a mutual majority exists within the mutual majority, then the majority becomes a collegiate over the minority, and the inner mutual majority solely decides the votes of this collegiate.
Systems which fail Condorcet but pass [[Mutual majority criterion|mutual majority]] can exclude voters outside the mutual majority from the vote, essentially becoming an election between the mutual majority.{{citation needed|date=November 2020}} IRV demonstrates this exclusion of up to 50 percent of voters, notably in the [[2009 Burlington mayoral election]] where the later rounds became a runoff between the mutual majority of voters favouring Andy Montroll and Bob Kiss. This can [[Recursion|recurse]]: if a mutual majority exists within the mutual majority, then the majority becomes a collegiate over the minority, and the inner mutual majority solely decides the votes of this collegiate.


==== Spoiler effects ====
==== Spoiler effects ====
Instant-runoff voting is vulnerable to spoiler effects, as it violates [[independence of irrelevant alternatives]] (see below). In the general case, instant-runoff voting can be susceptible to [[strategic nomination]]: whether or not a candidate decides to run at all can affect the result even if the new candidate cannot themselves win.<ref name="wds2" /> This is less likely to happen than under plurality, but much more likely than under [[ranked pairs]] or [[score voting]].

Instant-runoff voting is vulnerable to spoiler effects, as it violates [[independence of irrelevant alternatives]] (see below). In the general case, instant-runoff voting can be susceptible to [[strategic nomination]]: whether or not a candidate decides to run at all can affect the result even if the new candidate cannot themselves win.<ref name="wds">{{cite web |url=http://rangevoting.org/Burlington.html |title=Burlington Vermont 2009 IRV mayoral election |publisher=RangeVoting.org |access-date=17 April 2011}}</ref> This is less likely to happen than under plurality, but much more likely than under [[ranked pairs]] or [[score voting]].


==== Monotonicity criterion ====
==== Monotonicity criterion ====

{{Further|Monotonicity criterion#Instant-runoff voting and the two-round system are not monotonic}}
{{Further|Monotonicity criterion#Instant-runoff voting and the two-round system are not monotonic}}
The [[monotonicity criterion]] says that ranking a candidate higher on your ballot should not cause them to lose. The exact probability of a monotonicity failure is unknown, but with 3 equally popular candidates, the probabilities range from 14.5% under [[impartial culture]] to 8.5% in the case of a [[Left–right political spectrum|left–right spectrum]].<ref>{{cite web |last=Smith |first=Warren D. |title=Monotonicity and Instant Runoff Voting |url=http://rangevoting.org/Monotone.html |access-date=4 May 2011}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |first1=Dominique |last1=Lepelley |first2=Frederic |last2=Chantreuil |first3=Sven |last3=Berg |doi=10.1016/0165-4896(95)00804-7 |title=The likelihood of monotonicity paradoxes in run-off elections |journal=Mathematical Social Sciences |volume=31 |issue=3 |year=1996 |pages=133–146}}</ref>
The [[monotonicity criterion]] says that ranking a candidate higher on your ballot should not cause them to lose. The exact probability of a monotonicity failure is unknown, but with 3 equally popular candidates, the probabilities range from 14.5% under [[impartial culture]] to 8.5% in the case of a strict [[Left–right political spectrum|left–right spectrum]].<ref>{{cite web |last=Smith |first=Warren D. |title=Monotonicity and Instant Runoff Voting |url=http://rangevoting.org/Monotone.html |access-date=4 May 2011}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Lepelley |first1=Dominique |last2=Chantreuil |first2=Frederic |last3=Berg |first3=Sven |year=1996 |title=The likelihood of monotonicity paradoxes in run-off elections |journal=Mathematical Social Sciences |volume=31 |issue=3 |pages=133–146 |doi=10.1016/0165-4896(95)00804-7}}</ref>


==== Participation criterion ====
==== Participation criterion ====
The [[participation criterion]] says that candidates should not lose as a result of having "too many voters"—a set of ballots that all rank A>B should not switch the election winner from B to A. IRV fails this criterion: about 50 percent of elections where IRV elects a different candidate from plurality involve participation failures.<ref>{{cite journal |last=Ray |first=Depankar |year=1986 |title=On the practical possibility of a 'no show paradox' under the single transferable vote |journal=Mathematical Social Sciences |volume=11 |issue=2 |pages=183–189 |doi=10.1016/0165-4896(86)90024-7}}</ref>

The [[participation criterion]] says that candidates should not lose as a result of having "too many voters"—a set of ballots that all rank A>B should not switch the election winner from B to A. IRV fails this criterion: about 50 percent of elections where IRV elects a different candidate from plurality involve participation failures.<ref>{{cite journal |first=Depankar |last=Ray |title=On the practical possibility of a 'no show paradox' under the single transferable vote |doi=10.1016/0165-4896(86)90024-7 |volume=11 |issue=2 |journal=Mathematical Social Sciences |pages=183–189 |year=1986}}</ref>


==== Reversal symmetry criterion ====
==== Reversal symmetry criterion ====
The [[Reversal symmetry|reversal symmetry criterion]] states that the worst and best candidates should switch places if every ballot is reversed. In other words, it should not matter whether voters are asked to rank candidates from best-to-worst or worst-to-best. IRV fails this criterion: it is possible to construct an election where reversing the order of every ballot does not alter the final winner; that is, the first- and last-place finishers according to IRV are the same candidate.<ref name="WDSParticipationReversalSymmetry2">{{cite web |last=Smith |first=Warren D. |title=Lecture 'Mathematics and Democracy' |url=http://rangevoting.org/TBlecture.html#partic |access-date=12 May 2011}}</ref>

The [[reversal symmetry|reversal symmetry criterion]] states that the worst and best candidates should switch places if every ballot is reversed. In other words, it should not matter whether voters are asked to rank candidates from best-to-worst or worst-to-best. IRV fails this criterion: it is possible to construct an election where reversing the order of every ballot does not alter the final winner; that is, the first- and last-place finishers according to IRV are the same candidate.<ref name="WDSParticipationReversalSymmetry">{{cite web |last=Smith |first=Warren D. |title=Lecture 'Mathematics and Democracy' |url=http://rangevoting.org/TBlecture.html#partic |access-date=12 May 2011}}</ref>


==Examples==
==Examples==
Line 293: Line 283:


=== Five voters, three candidates ===
=== Five voters, three candidates ===

A simple example is provided in the accompanying table. Three candidates are running for election: Bob, Bill and Sue. There are five voters, "a" through "e". The voters each have one vote. They rank the candidates first, second and third in the order they prefer them. To win, a candidate must have a majority of vote; that is, three or more.
A simple example is provided in the accompanying table. Three candidates are running for election: Bob, Bill and Sue. There are five voters, "a" through "e". The voters each have one vote. They rank the candidates first, second and third in the order they prefer them. To win, a candidate must have a majority of vote; that is, three or more.


In Round 1, the first-choice rankings are tallied, with the results that Bob and Sue both have two votes and Bill has one. No candidate has a majority, so a second "instant runoff" round is required. Since Bill is in bottom place, he is eliminated. The ballot from any voter who ranked Bill first (in this example solely voter "c" ) gets modified as follows: the original second choice candidate for that voter becomes their new first choice, and their original third choice becomes their new second choice. This results in the Round 2 votes as seen below. This gives Sue three votes, which is a majority.
In Round 1, the first-choice rankings are tallied, with the results that Bob and Sue both have two votes and Bill has one. No candidate has a majority, so a second "instant runoff" round is required. Since Bill is in bottom place, he is eliminated. The ballot from any voter who ranked Bill first (in this example solely voter "c" ) gets modified as follows: the original second choice candidate for that voter becomes their new first choice, and their original third choice becomes their new second choice. This results in the Round 2 votes as seen below. This gives Sue three votes, which is a majority.
{| class="wikitable"
{| class="wikitable"
!
|-
! colspan="6" |Round 1
!|
! colspan="6" | Round 1
! colspan="6" |Round 2
|-! {{Diagonal split header|Candidates|Voters}}
! colspan="6" | Round 2
|-
! {{Diagonal split header|Candidates|Voters}} !! a !! b !! c !! d !! e
|| '''Votes'''
!a
!a
!b
!b
Line 310: Line 296:
!d
!d
!e
!e
! Votes
|'''Votes'''
!a
!b
!c
!d
!e
!Votes
|-
|-
|| Bob
|Bob
|1
|1||2||3||1||2|| style="background:#dfb;"|2||1||2||2||1||2|| style="background:#fbb;" |2 (eliminated)
|2
|3
|1
|2
|2
|1
|2
|2
|1
|2
|2
|-
|-
|| Sue
|Sue
|3
|3||1||2||3||1|| style="background:#dfb;"|2||2||1||1||2||1||style="background:#bfb;"|'''3'''
|1
|2
|3
|1
|2
|2
|1
|1
|2
|1
|'''3'''
|-
|-
|| Bill
|Bill
|2
|2||3||1||2||3|| style="background:#fbb;"|1 (eliminated)
|3
|1
|2
|3
|1 (eliminated)
|}
|}


===Tennessee capital election===
===Tennessee capital election===
{{Tenn_voting example}}
{{Tenn_voting example}}

It takes three rounds to determine a winner in this election:
It takes three rounds to determine a winner in this election:
{| class="wikitable"
{| class="wikitable"
!
!1st
!2nd
!3rd
|-
|-
|Knoxville
! !! 1st !! 2nd !! 3rd
|17%
|32%
|'''58%'''
|-
|-
|Memphis
|Knoxville || style="background:#dfb;" |17% || style="background:#dfb;" |32% || style="background:#bfb;" |'''58%'''
|42%
|42%
|42%
|-
|-
|Nashville
| Memphis|| style="background:#dfb;" |42% || style="background:#dfb;" |42% || style="background:#fbb;" |42% (eliminated)
|26%
|26%
|''Eliminated''
|-
|-
|Chattanooga
|Nashville|| style="background:#dfb;" |26% || style="background:#fbb;" |26% (eliminated)
|
|15%
| colspan="2" |''Eliminated''
|-
|}
|Chattanooga|| style="background:#fbb;" |15% (eliminated)
'''Round 1''' – In the first round, Chattanooga is eliminated.
| colspan="2" |
|}'''Round 1''' – In the first round, Chattanooga is eliminated.


'''Round 2''' – Chattanooga's votes go to Knoxville (the closest city to Chattanooga). Nashville is in last place and is therefore eliminated.
'''Round 2''' – Chattanooga's votes go to Knoxville (the closest city to Chattanooga). Nashville is in last place and is therefore eliminated.


Note that Nashville was both the [[Condorcet winner criterion|Condorcet winner]] and the "most central" city (the one supported by the [[Median voter theorem|median voter]]). This elimination is an example of a [[center squeeze]], where a popular consensus candidate is eliminated thanks to a [[Independence of irrelevant alternatives|spoiler effect]].
Note that Nashville was both the [[Condorcet winner criterion|Condorcet winner]] and the "most central" city (the one supported by the [[Median voter theorem|median voter]]). This elimination is an example of a [[center squeeze]], where a popular consensus candidate is eliminated thanks to a [[Independence of irrelevant alternatives|spoiler effect]].


'''Round 3''' – In the final round, Nashville's votes are redistributed to Knoxville, giving Knoxville a majority.
'''Round 3''' – In the final round, Nashville's votes are redistributed to Knoxville, giving Knoxville a majority.
Line 352: Line 384:
===1990 Irish presidential election===
===1990 Irish presidential election===
{{See also|Irish presidential election, 1990}}
{{See also|Irish presidential election, 1990}}
{|class="wikitable" style="float:right; text-align:center; margin:10px"
{| class="wikitable"
|+Irish presidential election, 1990<ref>{{cite web |title=Presidential Election November 1990 |url=http://www.electionsireland.org/result.cfm?election=1990P&cons=194 |access-date=23 November 2009 |work=ElectionsIreland.org}}</ref>
|-
|+Irish presidential election, 1990<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.electionsireland.org/result.cfm?election=1990P&cons=194 |title=Presidential Election November 1990 |work=ElectionsIreland.org |access-date=23 November 2009}}</ref>
|-
!Candidate
!Candidate
!colspan=2|Round 1
! colspan="2" |Round 1
!colspan=2|Round 2
! colspan="2" |Round 2
|-
|-
| style="text-align:left;" | [[Mary Robinson]]
|[[Mary Robinson]]
|612,265 || ''(38.9%)''
|612,265
|''(38.9%)''
|817,830 || ''(51.6%)''
|817,830
|''(51.6%)''
|-
|-
| style="text-align:left;" | [[Brian Lenihan Snr|Brian Lenihan]]
|[[Brian Lenihan Snr|Brian Lenihan]]
|694,484||''(43.8%)''
|694,484
|''(43.8%)''
|731,273||''(46.2%)''
|731,273
|''(46.2%)''
|-
|-
| style="text-align:left;" | [[Austin Currie]]
|[[Austin Currie]]
|267,902||''(16.9%)''
|267,902
|''(16.9%)''
|colspan=2 |
| colspan="2" |—
|-
|-
| style="text-align:left;" | Exhausted ballots
|Exhausted ballots
|9,444||''(0.6%)''
|9,444
|''(0.6%)''
|34,992||''(2.2%)''
|34,992
|''(2.2%)''
|-
|-
|Total
| style="text-align:left;" | Total
|1,584,095||''(100%)''
|1,584,095
|''(100%)''
|1,584,095||''(100%)''
|1,584,095
|''(100%)''
|}
|}
The [[1990 Irish presidential election]] provides an example of how instant-runoff voting can produce a different result from [[first-past-the-post voting]]. The three candidates were [[Brian Lenihan Snr|Brian Lenihan]] of the traditionally dominant [[Fianna Fáil]] party, [[Austin Currie]] of [[Fine Gael]], and [[Mary Robinson]], nominated by the [[Labour Party (Ireland)|Labour Party]] and the [[Workers' Party (Ireland)|Workers' Party]]. After the first count, Lenihan had the largest share of the first-choice rankings (and hence would have won a first-past-the-post vote), but no candidate attained the necessary majority. Currie was eliminated and his votes reassigned to the next preference ranked on each ballot; in this process, Robinson received 82 percent of Currie's votes, thereby overtaking Lenihan.<!--no cite: since only 3 candidates just simple ratio of extra votes in 2nd count.-->{{clear}}

The [[1990 Irish presidential election]] provides an example of how instant-runoff voting can produce a different result from [[first-past-the-post voting]]. The three candidates were [[Brian Lenihan Snr|Brian Lenihan]] of the traditionally dominant [[Fianna Fáil]] party, [[Austin Currie]] of [[Fine Gael]], and [[Mary Robinson]], nominated by the [[Labour Party (Ireland)|Labour Party]] and the [[Workers' Party (Ireland)|Workers' Party]]. After the first count, Lenihan had the largest share of the first-choice rankings (and hence would have won a first-past-the-post vote), but no candidate attained the necessary majority. Currie was eliminated and his votes reassigned to the next preference ranked on each ballot; in this process, Robinson received 82 percent of Currie's votes, thereby overtaking Lenihan.<!-- no cite: since only 3 candidates just simple ratio of extra votes in 2nd count. -->
{{clear}}


===2014 Prahran election (Victoria)===
===2014 Prahran election (Victoria)===
Another real-life example of IRV producing results different from first-past-the-post can be seen in the [[2014 Victorian state election|2014 Victorian general election]] in [[Electoral district of Prahran|Prahran]]. In this case, it was the candidate who initially finished ''third'' ([[Australian Greens|Greens]] candidate [[Sam Hibbins]]) in the first-round vote who went on to win. Hibbins would ultimately go on to defeat center-left [[Australian Labor Party|Australian Labor]] candidate Neil Pharaoh with the help of 31 voters who placed him in 6th place (third-to-last), despite losing the first five rounds of voting.<ref name="PrahranResults">{{cite web |url=https://www.vec.vic.gov.au/Results/State2014/distributionPrahranDistrict.html |title=State Election 2014: Prahran District (Distribution of preference votes) |work=Victorian Electoral Commission}}</ref> In the 7th round, Hibbins narrowly defeated [[Coalition (Australia)|Coalition]] candidate Clem Newton-Brown by a margin of 277 votes.
Another real-life example of IRV producing results different from first-past-the-post can be seen in the [[2014 Victorian state election|2014 Victorian general election]] in [[Electoral district of Prahran|Prahran]]. In this case, it was the candidate who initially placed third ([[Australian Greens|Green]] candidate [[Sam Hibbins]]). Hibbins would ultimately go on to defeat center-left [[Australian Labor Party|Australian Labor]] candidate Neil Pharaoh with the help of 31 voters who placed him in 6th place (third-to-last), despite losing the first five rounds of voting.<ref name="PrahranResults2">{{cite web |title=State Election 2014: Prahran District (Distribution of preference votes) |url=https://www.vec.vic.gov.au/Results/State2014/distributionPrahranDistrict.html |work=Victorian Electoral Commission}}</ref> In the 7th round, Hibbins narrowly defeated [[Coalition (Australia)|Coalition]] candidate Clem Newton-Brown by a margin of 277 votes.
{| class="wikitable sortable"

!Candidate
{| class="wikitable"
! colspan="2" |1st
!2nd
!3rd
!4th
!5th
!6th
! colspan="2" |7th
|-
|-
|[[Clem Newton-Brown]] ([[Liberal Party of Australia|LIB]])
!Candidate<ref name="PrahranResults" />
|44.8%
! colspan="2" |1st!! 2nd !! 3rd !! 4th !! 5th !! 6th !! colspan="2" |7th
|'''16,582'''
|-
|'''16,592'''
| [[Clem Newton-Brown]] ([[Liberal Party of Australia|LIB]])
|'''16,644'''
| 44.8%
|'''16,726'''
| '''16,582''' || '''16,592''' || '''16,644''' || '''16,726''' || '''16,843''' || '''17,076''' || style="background:#fbb;"|18,363
|'''16,843'''
|'''17,076'''
|18,363
|49.6%
|49.6%
|-
|-
| [[Sam Hibbins]] ([[Australian Greens|GRN]])
|[[Sam Hibbins]] ([[Australian Greens|GRN]])
| 24.8%
|24.8%
|9,160
| 9,160 || 9,171 || 9,218 || 9,310 || 9,403 || '''9,979''' || style="background:#dfb;"|'''18,640'''
|9,171
|9,218
|9,310
|9,403
|'''9,979'''
|'''18,640'''
|'''50.4%'''
|'''50.4%'''
|-
|-
| Neil Pharaoh ([[Australian Labor Party|ALP]])
|Neil Pharaoh ([[Australian Labor Party|ALP]])
| 25.9%
|25.9%
| '''9,586'''|| '''9,593'''|| '''9,639'''|| '''9,690'''|| '''9,758'''|| 9,948 (eliminated)
|'''9,586'''
|'''9,593'''
|'''9,639'''
|'''9,690'''
|'''9,758'''
|<s>9,948</s>
| colspan="2" |
| colspan="2" |''Eliminated''
|-
|-
| Eleonora Gullone ([[Animal Justice Party|AJP]])
|Eleonora Gullone ([[Animal Justice Party|AJP]])
| 2.3%
|2.3%
|837
| 837 || 860 || 891 || 928 || 999 (eliminated)
|860
| colspan="3" |
|891
|928
|<s>999</s>
| colspan="3" |''Eliminated''
|-
|-
| Jason Goldsmith ([[Independent (politician)|IND]])
|Jason Goldsmith ([[Independent (politician)|IND]])
| 0.7%
|0.7%
|247
| 247 || 263 || 316 || 349 (eliminated)
|263
| colspan="4" |
|316
|<s>349</s>
| colspan="4" |''Eliminated''
|-
|-
| Alan Walker ([[Family First Party|FFP]])
|Alan Walker ([[Family First Party|FFP]])
| 0.8%
|0.8%
|282
| 282 || 283 || 295 (eliminated)
|283
| colspan="5" |
|<s>295</s>
| colspan="5" |''Eliminated''
|-
|-
| Steve Stefanopoulos ([[Independent (politician)|IND]])
|Steve Stefanopoulos ([[Independent (politician)|IND]])
| 0.6%
|0.6%
|227
| 227 || 241 (eliminated)
|<s>241</s>
| colspan="6" |
| colspan="6" |''Eliminated''
|-
|-
| Alan Menadue ([[Independent (politician)|IND]])
|Alan Menadue ([[Independent (politician)|IND]])
| 0.2%
|0.2%
|<s>82</s>
| 82 (eliminated)
| colspan="7" |
| colspan="7" |''Eliminated''
|-
|-
! Total
!Total
| '''100%'''|| '''37,003'''
|'''100%'''
|'''37,003'''
|}
|}


Line 517: Line 586:
| +8980
| +8980
|}
|}
Under Burlington's second-ever IRV mayoral election in 2009, the winner, Bob Kiss, was elected over Andy Montroll even though he would have lost in a one-on-one election.<ref>{{cite web |last=Bouricious |first=Terry |date=13 March 2009 |title=Point/Counterpoint: Terry Bouricius Attempts To Rip Professor Gierzynski A New One Over Instant Runoff Voting Controversy (Now With All New Gierzynski Update!) |url=http://vermontdailybriefing.com/?p=1215 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20151019002702/http://vermontdailybriefing.com/?p=1215 |archive-date=19 October 2015 |access-date=27 September 2017 |website=Vermont Daily Briefing |quote=the 2009 election suffered from not only the 'thwarted majorities' or Condorcet's paradox, but also the 'no-show paradox' that shows that Wright voters who preferred Montroll over Kiss (that is, ranked Montroll 2nd) would have been better staying home and not voting at all.}}</ref><ref name=":12">{{cite web |last1=Gierzynski |first1=Anthony |last2=Hamilton |first2=Wes |last3=Smith |first3=Warren D. |date=March 2009 |title=Burlington Vermont 2009 IRV mayoral election |url=http://scorevoting.net/Burlington.html |access-date=1 October 2017 |website=RangeVoting.org |quote=Montroll was favored over Republican Kurt Wright 56% to 44% ... and over Progressive Bob Kiss 54% to 46% ... In other words, in voting terminology, Montroll was a 'beats-all winner,' also called a 'Condorcet winner' ... However, in the IRV election, Montroll came in third!}}</ref><ref name=":32">{{cite web |last=Olson |first=Brian |date=2009 |title=2009 Burlington Mayor IRV Failure |url=https://bolson.org/~bolson/2009/20090303_burlington_vt_mayor.html |access-date=1 October 2017 |website=bolson.org |quote=This is an IRV failure. The IRV result is clearly not what people actually wanted. More people liked Montroll over Kiss than the other way around, but IRV elected the loser.}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |last=Sheldon-hess |first=Dale |date=16 March 2009 |title=IRV Fails in Its Own Backyard |url=https://leastevil.blogspot.com/2009/03/irv-fails-in-its-own-backyard.html |access-date=27 September 2017 |website=The Least of All Evils |quote=Montroll would have beaten any other candidate in a one-on-one election.}}</ref>


The organization [[FairVote]], which advocates for IRV, called the election a success, noting that the system prevented an unpopular first-round winner ([[Kurt Wright]]) from winning, as would have happened under a [[Plurality voting|plurality]] voting system.<ref name="FairVote2">{{cite web |last=Bouricius |first=Terry |date=17 March 2009 |title=Response to Faulty Analysis of Burlington IRV Election |url=http://www.fairvote.org/response-to-faulty-analysis-of-burlington-irv-election |access-date=1 October 2017 |website=FairVote.org |quote=successfully prevented the election of the candidate who would likely have won under plurality rules, but would have lost to either of the other top finishers in a runoff}}</ref>
Under Burlington's second IRV mayoral election in 2009, the winner, Bob Kiss, was elected over Andy Montroll even though he would have lost in a one-on-one election.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://vermontdailybriefing.com/?p=1215 |title=Point/Counterpoint: Terry Bouricius Attempts To Rip Professor Gierzynski A New One Over Instant Runoff Voting Controversy (Now With All New Gierzynski Update!) |last=Bouricious |first=Terry |date=13 March 2009 |website=Vermont Daily Briefing |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20151019002702/http://vermontdailybriefing.com/?p=1215 |archive-date=19 October 2015 |access-date=27 September 2017 |quote=the 2009 election suffered from not only the 'thwarted majorities' or Condorcet's paradox, but also the 'no-show paradox' that shows that Wright voters who preferred Montroll over Kiss (that is, ranked Montroll 2nd) would have been better staying home and not voting at all.}}</ref><ref name=":1" /><ref name=":3">{{cite web |last=Olson |first=Brian |date=2009 |title=2009 Burlington Mayor IRV Failure |url=https://bolson.org/~bolson/2009/20090303_burlington_vt_mayor.html |access-date=1 October 2017 |website=bolson.org |quote=This is an IRV failure. The IRV result is clearly not what people actually wanted. More people liked Montroll over Kiss than the other way around, but IRV elected the loser.}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |url=https://leastevil.blogspot.com/2009/03/irv-fails-in-its-own-backyard.html |title=IRV Fails in Its Own Backyard |last=Sheldon-hess |first=Dale |date=16 March 2009 |website=The Least of All Evils |access-date=27 September 2017 |quote=Montroll would have beaten any other candidate in a one-on-one election.}}</ref>

The organization [[FairVote]], which advocates for IRV, called the election a success, noting that the system prevented an unpopular first-round winner ([[Kurt Wright]]) from winning, as would have happened under a [[Plurality voting|plurality]] voting system.<ref name="FairVote">{{cite web |url=http://www.fairvote.org/response-to-faulty-analysis-of-burlington-irv-election |title=Response to Faulty Analysis of Burlington IRV Election |last=Bouricius |first=Terry |date=17 March 2009 |website=FairVote.org |access-date=1 October 2017 |quote=successfully prevented the election of the candidate who would likely have won under plurality rules, but would have lost to either of the other top finishers in a runoff}}</ref>


However, the election prompted a storm of criticism from [[Voting reform|voting reform advocates]] and [[Political science|political scientists]], who pointed out that Andy Montroll was more popular than Bob Kiss and would have beaten Kiss by a comfortable margin of 8 percent in a one-on-one election.<ref name=":1">{{cite web |url=http://scorevoting.net/Burlington.html |title=Burlington Vermont 2009 IRV mayoral election |last1=Gierzynski |first1=Anthony |last2=Hamilton |first2=Wes |date=March 2009 |website=RangeVoting.org |access-date=1 October 2017 |quote=Montroll was favored over Republican Kurt Wright 56% to 44% ... and over Progressive Bob Kiss 54% to 46% ... In other words, in voting terminology, Montroll was a 'beats-all winner,' also called a 'Condorcet winner' ... However, in the IRV election, Montroll came in third! |last3=Smith |first3=Warren D.}}</ref><ref>{{Cite news |date=16 March 2009 |title=Burlington's 2009 Mayoral Election: Did IRV Fail The Voters? |url=https://integralpsychosis.wordpress.com/2009/03/16/burlingtons-2009-mayoral-election-did-irv-fail-the-voters/ |access-date=1 October 2017 |work=Integral Psychosis |quote=Montroll was the 'Beats-All winner' (aka the 'Condorcet winner') as he would have beaten both Wright (56% to 44%) and Kiss (54% to 46%) in head-to-head races, demonstrating that he was the preferred candidate by the majority of voters.}}</ref><ref name=":3" /> The chaotic campaign and its unpopular conclusion led Burlington voters to repeal IRV in a 2010 referendum by a vote of 52 to 48 percent.<ref>{{cite web |title=Instant run-off voting experiment ends in Burlington |url=http://www.rutlandherald.com/article/20100427/NEWS03/4270339/1004/NEWS03 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160304055602/http://www.rutlandherald.com/article/20100427/NEWS03/4270339/1004/NEWS03 |archive-date=4 March 2016 |access-date=15 December 2016 |website=Rutland Herald Online}}</ref><ref name="Ballotpedia">{{cite web |title=Burlington, Vermont, Question 4, Ranked-Choice Voting Amendment (March) |url=https://ballotpedia.org/Burlington,_Vermont,_Question_4,_Ranked-Choice_Voting_Amendment_(March_2021) |access-date=18 April 2021 |website=Ballotpedia.org}}</ref>
However, the election prompted a storm of criticism from [[Voting reform|voting reform advocates]] and [[Political science|political scientists]], who pointed out that Andy Montroll was more popular than Bob Kiss and would have beaten Kiss by a comfortable margin of 8 percent in a one-on-one election.<ref name=":12" /><ref>{{Cite news |date=16 March 2009 |title=Burlington's 2009 Mayoral Election: Did IRV Fail The Voters? |url=https://integralpsychosis.wordpress.com/2009/03/16/burlingtons-2009-mayoral-election-did-irv-fail-the-voters/ |access-date=1 October 2017 |work=Integral Psychosis |quote=Montroll was the 'Beats-All winner' (aka the 'Condorcet winner') as he would have beaten both Wright (56% to 44%) and Kiss (54% to 46%) in head-to-head races, demonstrating that he was the preferred candidate by the majority of voters.}}</ref><ref name=":32" /> Backlash to the results led Burlington voters to repeal IRV in a 2010 referendum by a vote of 52 to 48 percent.<ref>{{cite web |title=Instant run-off voting experiment ends in Burlington |url=http://www.rutlandherald.com/article/20100427/NEWS03/4270339/1004/NEWS03 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160304055602/http://www.rutlandherald.com/article/20100427/NEWS03/4270339/1004/NEWS03 |archive-date=4 March 2016 |access-date=15 December 2016 |website=Rutland Herald Online}}</ref><ref name="Ballotpedia2">{{cite web |title=Burlington, Vermont, Question 4, Ranked-Choice Voting Amendment (March) |url=https://ballotpedia.org/Burlington,_Vermont,_Question_4,_Ranked-Choice_Voting_Amendment_(March_2021) |access-date=18 April 2021 |website=Ballotpedia.org}}</ref>


The election was also a notable example of a participation and monotonicity failure, with Bob Kiss winning the election as a result of 750 ballots that ranked him in last place.<ref name=":1" /> Removing these ballots, or moving Bob Kiss from last to first place, would have caused Kiss to lose the election (by defeating Wright, allowing Montroll to advance to the final round).<ref name=":1" />
The election was also a notable example of a participation and monotonicity failure, with Bob Kiss winning the election as a result of 750 ballots that ranked him in last place.<ref name=":12" /> Removing these ballots, or moving Bob Kiss from last to first place, would have caused Kiss to lose the election (by defeating Wright, allowing Montroll to advance to the final round).<ref name=":12" />


{{Clear}}
{{Clear}}

Revision as of 05:28, 1 March 2024

Instant-runoff voting (IRV), also known as plurality with elimination or sequential loser plurality,[1] is a ranked-choice voting system that modifies plurality by introducing last-candidate elimination.[2][3] In the United Kingdom, it is generally called the alternative vote (AV).[4] In the United States and Australia, IRV is sometimes incorrectly referred to as ranked-choice voting (RCV)[5] or preferential voting[6][7] respectively, as a result of conflation with the class of all ranked-choice (preferential) voting systems.

IRV elections are a virtual (instant) variation on multiple-round voting. In each round, voters choose a favourite candidate; the last-place finisher is eliminated and another round is held. IRV elections automate this process by having voters rank candidates from first to last in order of preference. Voting can then be completed "instantly" by automatically reassigning each voter's ballot to their alternate (i.e. second) choice. This process continues until every candidate except one has been eliminated, at which point they are declared the winner.

IRV is used in national elections in several countries. In Australia, it is used to elect members of the federal House of Representatives,[8] as well as the lower houses in most states, and in some local government elections. It is the method used to elect the president of India, the president of Ireland,[9] and (in a modified form) the National Parliament of Papua New Guinea.[10] When used in city elections, the mayor is often elected through IRV.[11] It is also used in choosing the Academy Award for Best Picture,[citation needed] and a non-instant variant is used for the TV show American Idol[citation needed].

Election procedure

Process

Flowchart of Instant Runoff Voting

In instant-runoff voting, as with other ranked election methods, each voter orders candidates from first to last. On their ballot, voters mark a '1' beside their first-round vote, a '2' beside their second (alternative) vote, who receives their vote if the first candidate is eliminated; and so on until every candidate has been ranked.[12]

The instant-runoff procedure is as follows:

  1. Eliminate the candidate with the fewest votes.
  2. If only one candidate remains, elect this candidate and stop.
  3. Otherwise, go back to 1.

Ballots assigned to eliminated candidates are added to the totals of one of the remaining candidates based on the next preference ranked on each ballot. The process repeats until one candidate achieves a majority of the vote.

Terminology

Instant-runoff voting derives its name from the way the ballot count simulates a series of runoffs, similar to an exhaustive ballot system, except that voter preferences do not change between rounds.[13] It is also known as the alternative vote, transferable vote, ranked-choice voting (RCV), single-seat ranked-choice voting, or preferential voting.[14]

Britons and New Zealanders generally call IRV the "alternative vote" (AV).[15][16]. Australians, who use IRV for most single winner elections, call IRV "preferential voting".[17]

Jurisdictions in the United States IRV such as San Francisco, Minneapolis, Maine, and Alaska, have tended to use the term "ranked choice voting" in their laws. The San Francisco Department of Elections claimed the word "instant" in the term "instant runoff voting" could confuse voters into expecting results to be immediately available.[18][19] As a result of American influence, the term ranked-choice voting is often used in Canada as well.[20] American NGO FairVote has promoted the terminology "ranked choice voting" to refer to IRV, a choice that has caused controversy and accusations that the organization is attempting to obscure the existence of other ranked voting methods that could otherwise compete with IRV.[21][22]

IRV is occasionally referred to either as Hare's method[23] (after Thomas Hare) or as Ware's method, after the American William Robert Ware, to differentiate it from other ranked-choice voting methods such as Condorcet, Borda, or Bucklin voting.

When the single transferable vote (STV) method is applied to a single-winner election, it becomes IRV; the government of Ireland has called IRV "proportional representation" based on the fact that the same ballot form is used to elect its president by IRV and parliamentary seats by proportional representation (STV), but IRV is a non-proportional winner-take-all (single-winner) election method while STV elects multiple winners.[24] State law in South Carolina[25] and Arkansas[26] use "instant runoff" to describe the practice of having certain categories of absentee voters cast ranked-choice ballots before the first round of an election and counting those ballots in any subsequent runoff elections.

Properties, advantages, and disadvantages

Wasted votes and Condorcet winners

Compared to a plurality voting system that rewards only the top vote-getter, instant-runoff voting mitigates the problem of wasted votes.[27] However, it does not eliminate this problem, or ensure the election of a Condorcet winner, which is the candidate who would win a direct election against any other candidate in the race. These issues are illustrated in the following election:

In IRV for a polarized election between left, right, and center, the votes for B are not wasted, but the consensus candidate (B) is not elected
Simple election example
First choice A B C
Second choice B A C B
Voters 36% 10% 20% 34%
  • A wins plurality vote: second place preferences are ignored, so candidate A wins with 36 percent of the vote as against 34 percent for C and 30 percent (10+20) for B.
  • C wins IRV vote: candidate B gets the fewest first place votes so is eliminated in the first round. Candidate C gets more of B's second choice preferences than candidate A, winning the second round by 54 percent (20+34) to 46 percent (36+10). This result is the same as would occur if there was a primary with 3 candidates and a general election with the two remaining candidates (assuming no voters changed their preferences before the general election). Every voter gets a say in the final runoff, so no votes are wasted.
  • B wins Condorcet methods, for instance in IRV: in the first round candidates B and C are in last place, so they go head to head. Candidate A's second place votes go to candidate B, so candidate B wins 66 percent (36+10+20) to 34 percent over candidate C. In the second runoff round candidate C has been eliminated so candidates A and B go head to head. Candidate C's second place votes go to candidate B, so candidate B wins 64 percent (10+20+34) to 36 percent over candidate A. This can happen in a scenario where candidate B is a compromise candidate between polarizing candidates A and C.

Invalid, incomplete and exhausted ballots

All forms of ranked choice voting reduce to plurality when all ballots rank only one candidate. By extension, ballots for which all candidates ranked are eliminated are equivalent to votes for any non-winner in plurality, and considered exhausted ballots.

Because the ballot marking is more complex than X voting, there can be an increase in spoiled ballots. In Australia, voters are required to write a number beside every candidate,[28] and the rate of spoiled ballots is sometimes five times more common than plurality voting elections.[29][unreliable source?] Since Australia has compulsory voting, however, it is difficult to tell how many ballots are deliberately spoiled.[30] Where complete rankings are not required, a ballot may become inactive (be declared exhausted) if it is up for transfer and none of the candidates marked as lower ranked choices on that ballot are still in the running. In both cases, even in the instances of high rates of spoiled or exhausted votes, their number is much less than the amount of wasted votes under single-member plurality, where as much as 82 percent of votes cast do not produce representation.[31]

Most jurisdictions with IRV do not require complete rankings and may use columns to indicate preference instead of numbers. In American elections with IRV, more than 99 percent of voters typically cast a valid ballot.[32]

A 2015 study of four local US elections that used IRV found that inactive ballots occurred often enough in each of them that the winner of each election did not receive a majority of votes cast in the first round. The rate of inactive ballots in each election ranged from a low of 9.6 percent to a high of 27.1 percent.[33] As one point of comparison, the number of votes cast in the 190 regularly scheduled primary runoff elections for the US House and US Senate from 1994 to 2016 decreased from the initial primary on average by 39 percent, according to a 2016 study by FairVote.[34]

Resistance to strategy

Instant-runoff voting has notably high resistance to tactical voting when it elects the Condorcet winner. IRV does not demonstrate resistance to tactical voting when it does not elect the Condorcet winner.[citation needed]

Party strategizing

The complexity of strategy under instant-runoff voting means parties and candidates must often explain to voters how they should assign their lower preferences or provide them with a prepared ballot. This is especially common in Australia, where voters must rank all candidates to cast a valid ballot; as a result, over 95 percent of Australians used a pre-filled ballot in 2016.[35] Preference deals between parties (where one party's voters agree to place another party's voters second, in return for their doing the same) can lead to candidates winning seats off the back of far-downballot preferences voters were not even aware they had indicated. In one particularly infamous example, the Minor Party Alliance successfully manipulated this system to win several seats in 2016, despite receiving almost no first-preference votes.

Tactical voting

The Gibbard–Satterthwaite theorem demonstrates that no (deterministic, non-dictatorial) voting method using only the preference rankings of the voters can be entirely immune from tactical voting. This implies that IRV is susceptible to tactical voting in some circumstances.

Research concludes that IRV is one of the voting methods least vulnerable to tactical voting, with theorist Nicolaus Tideman noting that, "alternative voting is quite resistant to strategy",[36] and Australian political analyst Antony Green dismissing suggestions of tactical voting.[37] James Green-Armytage tested four ranked-choice methods, and found the alternative vote to be the second-most-resistant to tactical voting, though it was beaten by a class of AV-Condorcet hybrids, and did not resist strategic withdrawal by candidates well.[38] These analyses only apply to tactical voting, but not to other forms of manipulation; for example, Tideman and Robinette demonstrate a method by which a candidate modifies their campaign to appeal to a slightly broader range of voters, including those of a popular opponent, so as to "bracket" that opponent out (cause them to be eliminated earlier).[39]

By not meeting the monotonicity, Condorcet winner, and participation criteria, IRV may incentivize forms of tactical voting (such as compromising) when voters have sufficient information about other voters' preferences, such as from accurate pre-election polling.[40] FairVote mentions that monotonicity failure can lead to situations where "having more voters rank [a] candidate first, can cause [the candidate] to switch from being a winner to being a loser".[41] This occurs when a mutual majority exists which would elect a different candidate than the Condorcet candidate and a minority coalition running off to a single candidate exceeds one-half the size of this majority: the minority candidate cannot be eliminated until the mutual majority runs off to a majority winner. Moving the winner to the top of the minority ballots can shrink the minority sufficiently for their candidate to be eliminated, and their votes then cause the election of a different candidate.

Tactical voting in IRV seeks to alter the order of eliminations in early rounds, to ensure that the original winner is challenged by a stronger opponent in the final round. For example, in a three-party election where voters for both the left and right prefer the centrist candidate to stop the opposing candidate from winning, those voters who care more about defeating the opposition than electing their own candidate may cast a tactical first-preference vote for the centrist candidate.

The 2009 mayoral election in Burlington, Vermont, provides an example in which strategy theoretically could have worked but would have been unlikely in practice. In that election, most supporters of the candidate who lost in the final round (a Republican who led in first choices) preferred the Condorcet winner, a Democrat, to the IRV winner, the Progressive Party nominee. If 371 (24.7%) out of the 1,510 backers of the Republican candidate (who also preferred the Democrat over the Progressive candidate for mayor) had insincerely raised the Democrat from their second choice to their first (not changing their rankings relative to their least favourite candidate, the Progressive), the Democrat would then have advanced to the final round (instead of their favourite), defeated any opponent, and proceeded to win the IRV election.[40] This is an example of potential voter regret in that these voters who sincerely ranked their favourite candidate as first, find out after the fact that they caused the election of their least favourite candidate, which can lead to the voting tactic of compromising.

Spoiler effect

The spoiler effect is when a difference is made to the anticipated outcome of an election due to the presence on the ballot paper of a candidate who will lose. Most often this is when two or more politically similar candidates divide the vote for the more popular end of the political spectrum. That is, each receives fewer votes than a single opponent on the unpopular end of the spectrum who is disliked by the majority of voters but who wins from the advantage that, on that unpopular side, they are unopposed. Strategic nomination relies on triggering this situation, and requires understanding of both the electoral process and the demographics of the district.

Proponents of IRV claim that IRV eliminates the spoiler effect,[42][43][44][45] since IRV makes it safe to vote honestly for marginal parties: Under a plurality method, voters who sympathize most strongly with a marginal candidate are strongly encouraged to instead vote for a more popular candidate who shares some of the same principles, since that candidate has a much greater chance of being elected and a vote for the marginal candidate will not result in the marginal candidate's election. An IRV method reduces this problem, since the voter can rank the marginal candidate first and the mainstream candidate second; in the likely event that the fringe candidate is eliminated, the vote is not wasted but is transferred to the second preference.

However, when the third-party candidate is more competitive, they can still act as a spoiler under IRV,[46][47][48][49][50][51][52] by taking away first-choice votes from the more mainstream candidate until that candidate is eliminated, and then that candidate's second-choice votes helping a more-disliked candidate to win. In these scenarios, it would have been better for the third party voters if their candidate had not run at all (spoiler effect), or if they had voted dishonestly, ranking their favourite second rather than first (favourite betrayal).[53][54] This is the same bracketing effect exploited by Robinette and Tideman in their research on strategic campaigning, where a candidate alters their campaign to cause a change in voter honest choice, resulting in the elimination of a candidate who nevertheless remains more preferred by voters.

For example, in the 2009 Burlington, Vermont,mayoral election, if the Republican candidate who lost in the final instant runoff had not run, the Democratic candidate would have defeated the winning Progressive candidate. In that sense, the Republican candidate was a spoiler—(albeit for an opposing Democrat, rather than some political ally) even though leading in first choice support.[40][55][52] This also occurred in the 2022 Alaska's at-large congressional district special election. If Republican Sarah Palin, who lost in the final instant runoff, had not run, the more centrist Republican candidate, Nick Begich, would have defeated the winning Democratic candidate, Mary Peltola.[56][57]

In practice, IRV does not seem to discourage candidacies. In Australia's House of Representatives elections in 2007, for example, the average number of candidates in a district was seven, and at least four candidates ran in every district; notwithstanding the fact that Australia only has two major political parties. Every seat was won with a majority of the vote, including several where results would have been different under plurality voting.[58] A study of ballot image data found that all of the 138 RCV elections held in four Bay Area cities in California elected the Condorcet winner, including many with large fields of candidates and 46 where multiple rounds of counting were required to determine a winner.[59]

Proportionality

IRV is a single-winner application of the proportional voting system known as STV, with a Droop quota (50%+1). Like all winner-take-all voting methods, IRV tends to exaggerate the number of seats won by the largest parties; small parties without majority support in any given constituency are unlikely to earn seats in a legislature, although their supporters will be more likely to be part of the final choice between the two strongest candidates.[3] A simulation of IRV in the 2010 UK general election by the Electoral Reform Society concluded that the election would have altered the balance of seats among the three main parties, but the number of seats won by minor parties would have remained unchanged.[60]

Australia

Australia, a nation with a long record of using IRV for the election of legislative bodies, has had representation in its parliament broadly similar to that expected by plurality methods.

Medium-sized parties, such as the National Party of Australia, can co-exist with coalition partners such as the Liberal Party of Australia, and can compete against it without fear of losing seats to other parties due to vote splitting, although generally in practice these two parties only compete against each other when a sitting member of the coalition leaves Parliament.[61] IRV is more likely to result in legislatures where no single party has an absolute majority of seats (a hung parliament),[citation needed] but does not generally produce as fragmented a legislature as a fully proportional method, such as is used for the House of Representatives of the Netherlands, where coalitions of numerous small parties are needed for a majority.

Criticism

Voter confusion and legitimacy of elections

Some critics of IRV have noted that because of its greater complexity, IRV can create distrust among voters who misunderstand it. Often such criticism is related to allegations that IRV is a kind of plural voting. In Ann Arbor, arguments over IRV in letters to newspapers included the belief that IRV "gives minority candidate voters two votes", because some voters' ballots may count for their first choice in the first round and a lesser choice in a later round.[62] The argument that IRV represents plural voting is sometimes used in arguments over the "fairness" of the method, and has led to frequent legal challenges in the United States.[63]

The same argument was advanced in opposition to IRV in Maine. Governor Paul LePage claimed, ahead of the 2018 primary elections, that IRV would result in "one person, five votes", as opposed to "one person, one vote".[64] In litigation following the results of the 2018 election for Maine's 2nd congressional district, Representative Bruce Poliquin claimed that IRV allowed his opponents to "cast ballots for three different candidates in the same election".[65] Federal judge Lance Walker rejected this claim, and the 1st circuit court denied Poliquin's emergency appeal, leading to Poliquin dropping his claim.[66]

Similarity to plurality

Because it is effectively a "repeated plurality" vote, results with instant-runoff voting are typically very similar to those under plurality, and instant-runoff behaves similarly to plurality. This has led many commentators and voting reform advocates to question whether IRV is worth the substantial additional costs and complexity needed to ultimately elect the same winner. For example, instant-runoff voting fails the Condorcet criterion, meaning it fails to elect consensus winners.

Most instant-runoff voting elections are won by the candidate who leads in first-choice rankings, choosing the same winner as plurality voting. In Australia, the 1972 federal election had the highest proportion of winners who would not have won under first past the post—with only 14 out of 125 seats not won by the plurality candidate.[67]

Participation

The effect of IRV on voter turnout is difficult to assess. In a lengthy 2021 report, researchers at New America, a think tank based in Washington, D. C., said:[68]

With our sample of cases largely limited to municipal and often nonpartisan elections (in relatively engaged localities), the best we can say for RCV [ranked-choice voting], independent of timing considerations, is that it may increase local turnout from a pathetic baseline to a slightly less pathetic level by attracting more, and more diverse, candidates. However, if RCV is able to combine the primary and the general election into a single election, held in November alongside other national elections, it is likely to have a more powerful effect in boosting turnout.

The report concluded:[69]

And to the extent that RCV combines the primary and the general election into one, it increases turnout. However, many of the other hoped-for benefits, such as more diverse candidates (by gender, race, and ideology), higher turnout, and more viable parties, are harder to detect. Nor is there any evidence that RCV changes policy outcomes[...] In most elections, the candidate who would have won under plurality voting is also the candidate who won under ranked-choice voting.

History and use

History

This method was considered by Condorcet as early as 1788, though only to condemn it for its ability to eliminate a candidate preferred by a majority of voters.[70][71]

IRV can be seen as a special case of the single transferable vote method, which began use in the 1850s. It is historically known as Ware's method, due to the implementation of STV in 1871 at Harvard College by American architect William Robert Ware, who suggested it could also be used for single-winner elections.[72][73] Ware noted that the vote counting took only two or three hours, less time than required to count votes in the previous university election when limited voting was used and each voter cast five votes.[74] Unlike the single transferable vote in multi-seat elections, however, the only votes transferred are cast by backers of candidates who have been eliminated. There are no transfers of surplus votes as under STV.

The first known use of an IRV-like method in a governmental election was in the 1893 general election in the Colony of Queensland (in present-day Australia).[75] The variant used for this election was a "contingent vote", where all candidates but two are eliminated in the first round, with one of the last two elected by majority after votes of the others are transferred. Queensland used contingent voting until 1942, one of the longest uses of the system anywhere.[76]

IRV in its true form (what was called Alternative Voting at the time) was first used in Western Australia, in the 1908 state election. To form up a majority behind one candidate, candidates are dropped one by one. The lower houses of all Australian states (except Tasmania and ACT) and the Australian House of Representatives are elected through IRV. The last state to adopt AV was Queensland in 1962, It had switched from contingent voting to single-member plurality in 1942.[77] (Multi-winner STV of the Hare-Clark version was introduced for the Tasmanian House of Assembly at the 1909 state election. ACT used modified d'Hondt (a party-list PR system) to 1995 when it adopted STV.)[78]

IRV was introduced for federal (nationwide) elections in Australia after the Swan by-election in October 1918, in response to the rise of the conservative Country Party, representing small farmers. The Country Party split the non-Labor vote in conservative country areas, allowing Labor candidates to win without a majority of the vote. The conservative government of Billy Hughes introduced IRV (in Australia called "preferential voting") as a means of allowing competition between the Coalition parties without putting seats at risk. It was first used at the Corangamite by-election on 14 December 1918, and at a national level at the 1919 election.[79] IRV continued to benefit the Coalition until the 1990 election, when for the first time Labor obtained a net benefit from IRV.[80]

In 1990, for example, the small Baltic state of Estonia held its first post-Soviet elections under a combination of IRV and STV — a system which had been popularized by Rein Taagepera, an expatriate Estonian political scientist from the University of California.[81]

In 2000, Bosnia used IRV for its election.[81]

Global use

National level elections

Country Body or office Type of body or office Electoral system Total seats Notes
Australia House of Representatives Lower chamber of legislature IRV 151
Ireland President Head of State IRV
Dáil Éireann Lower chamber of legislature Single transferable vote (STV), by-elections using IRV 158[82]
Papua New Guinea National Parliament Unicameral legislature IRV 109
United States President (via Electoral College) Head of State and Government Alaska and Maine use IRV to select the state winner. In Maine, 2 electors are allocated to the winner and the others (currently 2) are allocated by congressional district, while in Alaska, the winner gets all electors of the state in the Electoral College system (as Alaska has only one at-large district, the effect is the same). 7 EVs[83] (out of 538)
House of Representatives Lower chamber of legislature IRV in Maine

Nonpartisan primary system with IRV in the second round (among top four candidates) in Alaska.[84][85][86][87]

3 (out of 435)
Senate Upper chamber of legislature 4 (out of 100)

Robert's Rules of Order

In the United States, the sequential elimination method used by IRV is described in Robert's Rules of Order Newly Revised as an example of ranked-choice voting that can be used to elect officers.[2] Robert's Rules note that ranked-choice systems (including IRV) are an improvement on simple plurality but recommend against runoff-based rules because they often prevent the emergence of a consensus candidate with broad support. The book instead recommends repeated balloting until some candidate manages to win a majority of votes. Two other books on American parliamentary procedure, The Standard Code of Parliamentary Procedure[88] and Riddick's Rules of Procedure,[89] take a similar stance.

Similar methods

Runoff voting

The term instant runoff voting is derived from the name of a class of voting methods called runoff voting. In runoff voting voters do not rank candidates in order of preference on a single ballot. Instead a similar effect is achieved by using multiple rounds of voting. All multi-round runoff voting methods allow voters to change their preferences in each round, incorporating the results of the prior round to influence their decision, which is not possible in IRV.

The runoff method closest to IRV is the exhaustive ballot. In this method—familiar to fans of the television show American Idol—one candidate is eliminated after each round, and many rounds of voting are used, rather than just two.[90] Because holding many rounds of voting on separate days is generally expensive, the exhaustive ballot is not used for large-scale, public elections.

A more practical form of runoff voting is the two-round system, which excludes all but the top-two candidates after the first round, rather than gradually eliminating candidates over a series of rounds. Eliminations can occur with or without allowing and applying preference votes to choose the final two candidates. A second round of voting or counting is only necessary if no candidate receives an overall majority of votes. This method is used in Mali, France and the Finnish and Slovenian presidential election.

Contingent vote

Top-two IRV

The contingent vote, also known as "top-two IRV" or the "supplementary vote", is the same as IRV, except that if no candidate achieves a majority in the first round of counting, all but the two candidates with the most votes are eliminated, and the second preferences for those ballots are counted. As in IRV, there is only one round of voting.

Under a variant of contingent voting used in Sri Lanka, and the elections for Mayor of London in the United Kingdom, voters rank a specified maximum number of candidates. In London, the supplementary vote allows voters to express first and second preferences only. Sri Lankan voters rank up to three candidates to elect the president of Sri Lanka.

While similar to "sequential-elimination" IRV, top-two can produce different results. Excluding more than one candidate after the first count might eliminate a candidate who would have won under sequential elimination IRV. Restricting voters to a maximum number of preferences is more likely to exhaust ballots if voters do not anticipate which candidates will finish in the top two. This can encourage voters to vote more tactically, by ranking at least one candidate they think is likely to win.

Conversely, a practical benefit of 'contingent voting' is expediency and confidence in the result with only two rounds.

Larger runoff process

IRV may also be part of a larger runoff process:

  • Some jurisdictions that hold runoff elections allow absentee (only) voters to submit IRV ballots, because the interval between votes is too short for a second round of absentee voting. IRV ballots enable absentee votes to count in the second (general) election round if their first choice does not make the runoff. Arkansas, South Carolina and Springfield, Illinois adopt this approach.[91] Louisiana uses it only for members of the United States Service or who reside overseas.[92]
  • IRV can quickly eliminate weak candidates in early rounds of an exhaustive ballot runoff, using rules to leave the desired number of candidates for further balloting.
  • IRV elections that require a majority of cast ballots but not that voters rank all candidates may require more than a single IRV ballot due to exhausted ballots.
  • Robert's Rules recommends preferential voting for elections by mail and requiring a majority of cast votes to elect a winner. For in-person elections, they recommend repeated balloting until one candidate receives an absolute majority of all votes cast; if candidates drop out as soon as it becomes clear they cannot win, this procedure will always elect a Condorcet winner. The use of repeated balloting allows voters to resolve Condorcet cycles by discussion and compromise, or by electing a consensus candidate who might have polled poorly in the initial election.[2]

Comparison to first-past-the-post

In the Australian federal election in September 2013, 135 out of the 150 House of Representatives seats (or 90 percent) were won by the candidate who led on first preferences. The other 15 seats (10 percent) were won by the candidate who placed second on first preferences.[93]

Variations

Example of a full preferential ballot paper from the Australian House of Representatives

A number of IRV methods, varying as to ballot design and as to whether or not voters are obliged to provide a full list of preferences, are in use in different countries and local governments.

In an optional preferential voting system, voters can give a preference to as many candidates as they wish. They may make only a single choice, known as "bullet voting", and some jurisdictions accept a single box marked with an "X" (as opposed to a numeral "1") as valid for the first preference. This may result in exhausted ballots, where all of a voter's preferences are eliminated before a candidate is elected, such that the "majority" in the final round may only constitute a minority fraction of all ballots cast. Optional preferential voting is used for elections for the President of Ireland as well as some elections in New South Wales and Queensland.[94][95]

In a full-preferential voting method, voters are required to mark a preference for every candidate standing.[96] Ballots that do not contain a complete ordering of all candidates are in some jurisdictions considered spoilt or invalid, even if there are only two candidates standing. This can become burdensome in elections with many candidates and can lead to "donkey voting", in which some voters simply choose candidates at random or in top-to-bottom order, or a voter may order his or her preferred candidates and then fill in the remainder on a donkey basis. Full preferential voting is used for elections to the Australian federal parliament and for most state parliaments.

Other methods only allow marking preferences for a maximum of the voter's top three favourites, a form of partial preferential voting.[97]

A version of instant-runoff voting applying to the ranking of parties was first proposed for elections in Germany in 2013[98] as spare vote.[99]

Voting method criteria

Scholars rate voting methods using mathematically derived voting method criteria, which describe desirable features of a method. No ranked-preference method can meet all of the criteria, because some of them are mutually exclusive, as shown by statements such as Arrow's impossibility theorem and the Gibbard–Satterthwaite theorem.

Many of the mathematical criteria by which voting methods are compared were formulated for voters with ordinal preferences. If voters vote according to the same ordinal preferences in both rounds, criteria can be applied to two-round systems of runoffs, and in that case, each of the criteria failed by IRV is also failed by the two-round system as they relate to automatic elimination of trailing candidates. Partial results exist for other models of voter behavior in the two-round method: see the two-round system article's criterion compliance section for more information.

Satisfied criteria

The Condorcet loser criterion states that "if a candidate would lose a head-to-head competition against every other candidate, then that candidate must not win the overall election." IRV (like all voting methods with a final runoff round) meets this criterion, since the Condorcet loser cannot win a runoff, however IRV can still elect the "second-worst" candidate, when the two worst candidates are the only ones remaining in the final round.[100]

The independence of clones criterion states that "the election outcome remains the same even if an identical candidate who is equally preferred decides to run". IRV meets this criterion.[101] The later-no-harm criterion states that "if a voter alters the order of candidates lower in his/her preference (e.g. swapping the second and third preferences), then that does not affect the chances of the most preferred candidate being elected".

The majority criterion states that "if one candidate is preferred by an absolute majority of voters, then that candidate must win". The mutual majority criterion states that "if an absolute majority of voters prefer every member of a group of candidates to every candidate not in that group, then one of the preferred group must win". Note that this is satisfied because when all but one candidate that a mutual majority prefer is eliminated, the votes of the majority all flow to the remaining candidate, in contrast to FPTP, where the majority would be treated as separate small groups. The resolvability criterion states that "the probability of an exact tie must diminish as more votes are cast".

Pathologies of IRV

Spoiler effects

Instant-runoff voting is vulnerable to spoiler effects, as it violates independence of irrelevant alternatives (see below). In the general case, instant-runoff voting can be susceptible to strategic nomination: whether or not a candidate decides to run at all can affect the result even if the new candidate cannot themselves win.[102] This is less likely than under plurality voting

Condorcet winner criterion

The Condorcet winner criterion states that "if a candidate would win a head-to-head competition against every other candidate, then that candidate must win the overall election". It is incompatible with the later-no-harm criterion, so IRV does not meet this criterion.

IRV is more likely to elect the Condorcet winner than plurality voting and traditional runoff elections. The California cities of Oakland, San Francisco and San Leandro in 2010 provide an example; there were a total of four elections in which the plurality-voting leader in first-choice rankings was defeated, and in each case the IRV winner was the Condorcet winner, including a San Francisco election in which the IRV winner was in third place in first choice rankings.[103]

Systems which fail Condorcet but pass mutual majority can exclude voters outside the mutual majority from the vote, essentially becoming an election between the mutual majority.[citation needed] IRV demonstrates this exclusion of up to 50 percent of voters, notably in the 2009 Burlington mayoral election where the later rounds became a runoff between the mutual majority of voters favouring Andy Montroll and Bob Kiss. This can recurse: if a mutual majority exists within the mutual majority, then the majority becomes a collegiate over the minority, and the inner mutual majority solely decides the votes of this collegiate.

Spoiler effects

Instant-runoff voting is vulnerable to spoiler effects, as it violates independence of irrelevant alternatives (see below). In the general case, instant-runoff voting can be susceptible to strategic nomination: whether or not a candidate decides to run at all can affect the result even if the new candidate cannot themselves win.[102] This is less likely to happen than under plurality, but much more likely than under ranked pairs or score voting.

Monotonicity criterion

The monotonicity criterion says that ranking a candidate higher on your ballot should not cause them to lose. The exact probability of a monotonicity failure is unknown, but with 3 equally popular candidates, the probabilities range from 14.5% under impartial culture to 8.5% in the case of a strict left–right spectrum.[104][105]

Participation criterion

The participation criterion says that candidates should not lose as a result of having "too many voters"—a set of ballots that all rank A>B should not switch the election winner from B to A. IRV fails this criterion: about 50 percent of elections where IRV elects a different candidate from plurality involve participation failures.[106]

Reversal symmetry criterion

The reversal symmetry criterion states that the worst and best candidates should switch places if every ballot is reversed. In other words, it should not matter whether voters are asked to rank candidates from best-to-worst or worst-to-best. IRV fails this criterion: it is possible to construct an election where reversing the order of every ballot does not alter the final winner; that is, the first- and last-place finishers according to IRV are the same candidate.[107]

Examples

Some examples of IRV elections are given below. The first two (fictional elections) demonstrate the principle of IRV. The others offer examples of the results of real elections.

Five voters, three candidates

A simple example is provided in the accompanying table. Three candidates are running for election: Bob, Bill and Sue. There are five voters, "a" through "e". The voters each have one vote. They rank the candidates first, second and third in the order they prefer them. To win, a candidate must have a majority of vote; that is, three or more.

In Round 1, the first-choice rankings are tallied, with the results that Bob and Sue both have two votes and Bill has one. No candidate has a majority, so a second "instant runoff" round is required. Since Bill is in bottom place, he is eliminated. The ballot from any voter who ranked Bill first (in this example solely voter "c" ) gets modified as follows: the original second choice candidate for that voter becomes their new first choice, and their original third choice becomes their new second choice. This results in the Round 2 votes as seen below. This gives Sue three votes, which is a majority.

Round 1 Round 2
a b c d e Votes a b c d e Votes
Bob 1 2 3 1 2 2 1 2 2 1 2 2
Sue 3 1 2 3 1 2 2 1 1 2 1 3
Bill 2 3 1 2 3 1 (eliminated)

Tennessee capital election

Tennessee and its four major cities: Memphis in the far west; Nashville in the center; Chattanooga in the east; and Knoxville in the far northeast

Suppose that Tennessee is holding an election on the location of its capital. The population is concentrated around four major cities. All voters want the capital to be as close to them as possible. The options are:

  • Memphis, the largest city, but far from the others (42% of voters)
  • Nashville, near the center of the state (26% of voters)
  • Chattanooga, somewhat east (15% of voters)
  • Knoxville, far to the northeast (17% of voters)

The preferences of each region's voters are:

42% of voters
Far-West
26% of voters
Center
15% of voters
Center-East
17% of voters
Far-East
  1. Memphis
  2. Nashville
  3. Chattanooga
  4. Knoxville
  1. Nashville
  2. Chattanooga
  3. Knoxville
  4. Memphis
  1. Chattanooga
  2. Knoxville
  3. Nashville
  4. Memphis
  1. Knoxville
  2. Chattanooga
  3. Nashville
  4. Memphis


It takes three rounds to determine a winner in this election:

1st 2nd 3rd
Knoxville 17% 32% 58%
Memphis 42% 42% 42%
Nashville 26% 26% Eliminated
Chattanooga 15% Eliminated

Round 1 – In the first round, Chattanooga is eliminated.

Round 2 – Chattanooga's votes go to Knoxville (the closest city to Chattanooga). Nashville is in last place and is therefore eliminated.

Note that Nashville was both the Condorcet winner and the "most central" city (the one supported by the median voter). This elimination is an example of a center squeeze, where a popular consensus candidate is eliminated thanks to a spoiler effect.

Round 3 – In the final round, Nashville's votes are redistributed to Knoxville, giving Knoxville a majority.

For comparison, note that a plurality vote would elect Memphis, even though most citizens consider it the worst choice, because 42 percent is larger than any other single city. As Nashville is a Condorcet winner, Condorcet methods would elect Nashville.

This election is an example of a participation failure because Memphis eliminated Nashville in round 3. If Memphis lost half its population, Nashville (the Memphis voters' second choice) would have won the election instead of Knoxville (the Memphis voters' last choice).

1990 Irish presidential election

Irish presidential election, 1990[108]
Candidate Round 1 Round 2
Mary Robinson 612,265 (38.9%) 817,830 (51.6%)
Brian Lenihan 694,484 (43.8%) 731,273 (46.2%)
Austin Currie 267,902 (16.9%)
Exhausted ballots 9,444 (0.6%) 34,992 (2.2%)
Total 1,584,095 (100%) 1,584,095 (100%)

The 1990 Irish presidential election provides an example of how instant-runoff voting can produce a different result from first-past-the-post voting. The three candidates were Brian Lenihan of the traditionally dominant Fianna Fáil party, Austin Currie of Fine Gael, and Mary Robinson, nominated by the Labour Party and the Workers' Party. After the first count, Lenihan had the largest share of the first-choice rankings (and hence would have won a first-past-the-post vote), but no candidate attained the necessary majority. Currie was eliminated and his votes reassigned to the next preference ranked on each ballot; in this process, Robinson received 82 percent of Currie's votes, thereby overtaking Lenihan.

2014 Prahran election (Victoria)

Another real-life example of IRV producing results different from first-past-the-post can be seen in the 2014 Victorian general election in Prahran. In this case, it was the candidate who initially placed third (Green candidate Sam Hibbins). Hibbins would ultimately go on to defeat center-left Australian Labor candidate Neil Pharaoh with the help of 31 voters who placed him in 6th place (third-to-last), despite losing the first five rounds of voting.[109] In the 7th round, Hibbins narrowly defeated Coalition candidate Clem Newton-Brown by a margin of 277 votes.

Candidate 1st 2nd 3rd 4th 5th 6th 7th
Clem Newton-Brown (LIB) 44.8% 16,582 16,592 16,644 16,726 16,843 17,076 18,363 49.6%
Sam Hibbins (GRN) 24.8% 9,160 9,171 9,218 9,310 9,403 9,979 18,640 50.4%
Neil Pharaoh (ALP) 25.9% 9,586 9,593 9,639 9,690 9,758 9,948 Eliminated
Eleonora Gullone (AJP) 2.3% 837 860 891 928 999 Eliminated
Jason Goldsmith (IND) 0.7% 247 263 316 349 Eliminated
Alan Walker (FFP) 0.8% 282 283 295 Eliminated
Steve Stefanopoulos (IND) 0.6% 227 241 Eliminated
Alan Menadue (IND) 0.2% 82 Eliminated
Total 100% 37,003

2009 Burlington mayoral election

Burlington mayoral election, 2009 (Round by round analysis of votes)
Candidates 1st round 2nd round 3rd round
Candidate Party Votes ± Votes ± Votes ±
Bob Kiss Progressive 2585 +2585 2981 +396 4313 +1332
Kurt Wright Republican 2951 +2951 3294 +343 4061 +767
Andy Montroll Democrat 2063 +2063 2554 +491 0 −2554
Dan Smith Independent 1306 +1306 0 −1306
James Simpson Green 35 +35 0 −35
Write-in 36 +36 0 −36
Exhausted pile 4 +4 151 +147 606 +455
TOTALS[110] 8980 +8980

Under Burlington's second-ever IRV mayoral election in 2009, the winner, Bob Kiss, was elected over Andy Montroll even though he would have lost in a one-on-one election.[111][112][113][114]

The organization FairVote, which advocates for IRV, called the election a success, noting that the system prevented an unpopular first-round winner (Kurt Wright) from winning, as would have happened under a plurality voting system.[115]

However, the election prompted a storm of criticism from voting reform advocates and political scientists, who pointed out that Andy Montroll was more popular than Bob Kiss and would have beaten Kiss by a comfortable margin of 8 percent in a one-on-one election.[112][116][113] Backlash to the results led Burlington voters to repeal IRV in a 2010 referendum by a vote of 52 to 48 percent.[117][118]

The election was also a notable example of a participation and monotonicity failure, with Bob Kiss winning the election as a result of 750 ballots that ranked him in last place.[112] Removing these ballots, or moving Bob Kiss from last to first place, would have caused Kiss to lose the election (by defeating Wright, allowing Montroll to advance to the final round).[112]

Burlington mayoral election, 2009 (summary analysis)
Party Candidate Maximum
round
Maximum
votes
Share in
maximum
round
Maximum votes
First round votesTransfer votes


Progressive Bob Kiss 3 4,313 48.0%
Republican Kurt Wright 3 4,061 45.2%
Democratic Andy Montroll 2 2,554 28.4%
Independent Dan Smith 1 1,306 14.5%
Green James Simpson 1 35 0.4%
Write-in 1 36 0.4%
Exhausted votes 606 6.7%

Comparison to other voting systems

Comparison of single-winner voting systems
Criterion


Method
Majority winner Majority loser Mutual majority Condorcet winner[Tn 1] Condorcet loser Smith[Tn 1] Smith-IIA[Tn 1] IIA/LIIA[Tn 1] Clone­proof Mono­tone Participation Later-no-harm[Tn 1] Later-no-help[Tn 1] No favorite betrayal[Tn 1] Ballot

type

First-past-the-post voting Yes No No No No No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes No Single mark
Anti-plurality No Yes No No No No No No No Yes Yes No No Yes Single mark
Two round system Yes Yes No No Yes No No No No No No Yes Yes No Single mark
Instant-runoff Yes Yes Yes No Yes No No No Yes No No Yes Yes No Ran­king
Coombs Yes Yes Yes No Yes No No No No No No No No Yes Ran­king
Nanson Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No No No No No No Ran­king
Baldwin Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No No No No No No Ran­king
Tideman alternative Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes No No No No No Ran­king
Minimax Yes No No Yes[Tn 2] No No No No No Yes No No[Tn 2] No No Ran­king
Copeland Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No Yes No No No No Ran­king
Black Yes Yes No Yes Yes No No No No Yes No No No No Ran­king
Kemeny–Young Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes LIIA Only No Yes No No No No Ran­king
Ranked pairs Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes LIIA Only Yes Yes No[Tn 3] No No No Ran­king
Schulze Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes No[Tn 3] No No No Ran­king
Borda No Yes No No Yes No No No No Yes Yes No Yes No Ran­king
Bucklin Yes Yes Yes No No No No No No Yes No No Yes No Ran­king
Approval Yes No No No No No No Yes[Tn 4] Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes Appr­ovals
Majority Judgement No No[Tn 5] No[Tn 6] No No No No Yes[Tn 4] Yes Yes No[Tn 3] No Yes Yes Scores
Score No No No No No No No Yes[Tn 4] Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes Scores
STAR No Yes No No Yes No No No No Yes No No No No Scores
Random ballot[Tn 7] No No No No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Single mark
Sortition[Tn 8] No No No No No No No Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes None
Table Notes
  1. ^ a b c d e f g Condorcet's criterion is incompatible with the consistency, participation, later-no-harm, later-no-help, and sincere favorite criteria.
  2. ^ a b A variant of Minimax that counts only pairwise opposition, not opposition minus support, fails the Condorcet criterion and meets later-no-harm.
  3. ^ a b c In Highest median, Ranked Pairs, and Schulze voting, there is always a regret-free, semi-honest ballot for any voter, holding all other ballots constant and assuming they know enough about how others will vote. Under such circumstances, there is always at least one way for a voter to participate without grading any less-preferred candidate above any more-preferred one.
  4. ^ a b c Approval voting, score voting, and majority judgment satisfy IIA if it is assumed that voters rate candidates independently using their own absolute scale. For this to hold, in some elections, some voters must use less than their full voting power despite having meaningful preferences among viable candidates.
  5. ^ Majority Judgment may elect a candidate uniquely least-preferred by over half of voters, but it never elects the candidate uniquely bottom-rated by over half of voters.
  6. ^ Majority Judgment fails the mutual majority criterion, but satisfies the criterion if the majority ranks the mutually favored set above a given absolute grade and all others below that grade.
  7. ^ A randomly chosen ballot determines winner. This and closely related methods are of mathematical interest and included here to demonstrate that even unreasonable methods can pass voting method criteria.
  8. ^ Where a winner is randomly chosen from the candidates, sortition is included to demonstrate that even non-voting methods can pass some criteria.



See also

References

  1. ^ Koether, Robb T. "The Plurality-with-Elimination Method" (PDF).
  2. ^ a b c Robert, Henry (2011). Robert's Rules of Order Newly Revised (11th ed.). Da Capo Press. pp. 425–428. ISBN 978-0-306-82020-5.
  3. ^ a b "Types of Voting Systems". Mtholyoke.edu. 8 April 2005. Retrieved 6 May 2010.
  4. ^ "Alternative Vote". www.electoral-reform.org.uk. Retrieved 30 May 2019.
  5. ^ FairVote.org. "Ranked Choice Voting / Instant Runoff". FairVote. Retrieved 30 May 2019.
  6. ^ "Explainer: What is preferential voting?". SBS News. Retrieved 30 May 2019.
  7. ^ "Preferential voting". Australian Electoral Commission. Retrieved 17 November 2020.
  8. ^ "Australian Electoral Commission". Aec.gov.au. 23 April 2014. Retrieved 30 April 2014.
  9. ^ "Ireland Constitution, Article 12(2.3)". International Constitutional Law. 1995. Retrieved 15 February 2008.
  10. ^ "Understanding the Limited Preferential Voting system – EMTV Online". 10 April 2017. Retrieved 18 February 2021.
  11. ^ Rek, Municipal Elections in Edmonton
  12. ^ "How to make your vote count" (PDF). Australian Electoral Commission. Retrieved 22 March 2023.
  13. ^ "Second Report: Election of a Speaker". House of Commons Select Committee on Procedure. 15 February 2001. Retrieved 18 February 2008.
  14. ^ Cary, David (1 January 2011). "Estimating the Margin of Victory for Instant-runoff Voting". Proceedings of the 2011 Conference on Electronic Voting Technology/Workshop on Trustworthy Elections. EVT/WOTE'11: 3.
  15. ^ "BBC News – Alternative vote". bbc.com. British Broadcasting Corporation. 8 February 2012. Retrieved 9 October 2019.
  16. ^ "Opinion: OUSA Needs the Alternative Vote". Critic – Te Arohi. Otago, New Zealand: Otago University Students' Association. 30 September 2017. Retrieved 9 October 2019.
  17. ^ "Liberal plan to change federal voting laws may have crossbench support". The Guardian. 11 December 2020. Retrieved 13 February 2021.
  18. ^ Appendix D, Instant Runoff Voting, San Francisco Charter § 13.102 https://sfgov.org/ccsfgsa/sites/default/files/Voting%20Systems%20Task%20Force/AppendixD__.pdf.
  19. ^ Arntz, John (2 February 2005). "Ranked-Choice Voting: A Guide for Candidates" (PDF). Department of Elections: City and County of San Francisco. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2 December 2008. Retrieved 25 August 2009 – via FairVote. In San Francisco, ranked-choice voting is sometimes called 'instant run-off voting.' The Department of Elections generally uses the term ranked-choice voting, because it describes the voting method—voters are directed to rank their first-, second- and third-choice candidates. The Department also uses the term ranked-choice voting because the word 'instant' might create an expectation that final results will be available immediately after the polls close on election night.
  20. ^ "What is Ranked Choice Voting?". City of London. Archived from the original on 26 February 2018.
  21. ^ "How RCV Works". FairVote. 17 August 2019. Retrieved 17 August 2018.
  22. ^ "What is Ranked Choice Voting?". City of London. Archived from the original on 26 February 2018.
  23. ^ Pacuit, Eric (24 June 2019) [3 August 2011]. "Voting Methods". In Zalta, Edward N. (ed.). The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Fall 2019 ed.) – via plato.stanford.edu.
  24. ^ "Proportional Representation". Citizens Information Board. Retrieved 17 August 2019.
  25. ^ "South Carolina General Assembly : 116th Session, 2005–2006". Scstatehouse.gov. Retrieved 1 March 2015.
  26. ^ "Bill Information". Arkleg.state.ar.us. Retrieved 28 January 2015.
  27. ^ J. R. Chamberlin and M. D. Cohen, ‘Toward Applicable Social Choice Theory...’, (1978).
  28. ^ "Voting in the House of Representatives". Australian Electoral Commission. 28 June 2016. Retrieved 9 December 2018.
  29. ^ "Busting the Myths of AV". No2av.org. 25 October 2010. Archived from the original on 8 February 2011. Retrieved 17 April 2011.
  30. ^ "Informal Voting – Two Ways of Allowing More Votes to Count". ABC Elections. 28 February 2011. Retrieved 15 August 2011.
  31. ^ https://www.toronto.ca/wp-content/uploads/2017/08/9059-election-2014-clerksofficialdeclarationofresults.pdf
  32. ^ "Instant Runoff Voting and Its Impact on Racial Minorities" (PDF). New America Foundation. 1 August 2008. Archived from the original (PDF) on 15 June 2011. Retrieved 15 August 2011.
  33. ^ Burnett, Craig M.; Kogan, Vladimir (March 2015). "Ballot (and voter) 'exhaustion' under Instant Runoff Voting: An examination of four ranked-choice elections". Electoral Studies. 37: 41–49. doi:10.1016/j.electstud.2014.11.006. S2CID 11159132.
  34. ^ "Box".
  35. ^ "The new Senate voting system and the 2016 election, Figure 3" (PDF). Parliament of Australia, Department of Parliamentary Services. 25 January 2018.
  36. ^ Bartholdi III, John J.; Orlin, James B. (1991). "Single transferable vote resists strategic voting" (PDF). Social Choice and Welfare. 8 (4): 341–354. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.127.97. doi:10.1007/bf00183045. S2CID 17749613.
  37. ^ "How to Vote Guide". Antony Green's Election Blog. 11 October 2011. Retrieved 29 January 2017. What is the best way to vote strategically? The best strategic vote is to number the candidates in the order you would like to see them elected. ... in electorate of more than 90,000 voters, and without perfect knowledge, such a strategy is not possible.
  38. ^ Green-Armytage, James. "Four Condorcet-Hare Hybrid Methods for Single-Winner Elections" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 3 June 2013. Retrieved 31 May 2011.
  39. ^ Robinette, Robbie; Tideman, Nicolaus (12 March 2021). What a Difference a Voting Rule Makes. Savannah, Georgia.
  40. ^ a b c Warren Smith (2009) "Burlington Vermont 2009 IRV mayor election; Thwarted-majority, non-monotonicity & other failures (oops)"
  41. ^ "Monotonicity and IRV – Why the Monotonicity Criterion is of Little Import". Archive.fairvote.org. Retrieved 17 April 2011.
  42. ^ "Instant Run-Off Voting". archive.fairvote.org. Retrieved 29 January 2017. IRV removes the "spoiler effect" whereby minor party or independent candidates knock off major party candidates, increasing the choices available to the voters.
  43. ^ "Cal IRV FAQ". www.cfer.org. Retrieved 29 January 2017. IRV completely eliminates the 'spoiler' effect – that is, votes split between a weak and a strong candidate won't cause the strong candidate to lose if s/he is the second choice of the weak candidate's voters.
  44. ^ "OP-ED | No More Spoilers? Instant Runoff Voting Makes Third Parties Viable, Improves Democracy". CT News Junkie. Retrieved 20 April 2017. Instant-runoff voting ends the spoiler effect forever
  45. ^ CGP Grey (6 April 2011), The Alternative Vote Explained, retrieved 20 April 2017, Alternative Vote: Stops the Spoiler Effect
  46. ^ Borgers, Christoph (2010). Mathematics of Social Choice: Voting, Compensation, and Division. SIAM. ISBN 9780898716955. Candidates C and D spoiled the election for B ... With them in the running, A won, whereas without them in the running, B would have won. ... Instant runoff voting ... does not do away with the spoiler problem entirely, although it ... makes it less likely
  47. ^ Poundstone, William (2009). Gaming the Vote: Why Elections Aren't Fair (and What We Can Do About It). Farrar, Straus and Giroux. ISBN 9781429957649. IRV is excellent for preventing classic spoilers-minor candidates who irrationally tip the election from one major candidate to another. It is not so good when the 'spoiler' has a real chance of winning
  48. ^ "The Spoiler Effect". The Center for Election Science. 20 May 2015. Retrieved 29 January 2017.
  49. ^ "The Problem with Instant Runoff Voting". minguo.info. Retrieved 29 January 2017. After a minor party is strong enough to win, on the other hand, a vote for them could have the same spoiler effect that it could have under the current plurality system
  50. ^ "Example to demonstrate how IRV leads to 'spoilers,' 2-party domination". RangeVoting.org. Retrieved 29 January 2017. IRV means betraying your true favorite third party candidate pays off. Voting third party can mean wasting your vote under IRV, just like under plurality.
  51. ^ The Center for Election Science (2 December 2013), Favorite Betrayal in Plurality and Instant Runoff Voting, retrieved 29 January 2017
  52. ^ a b Bristow-Johnson, R. (2023). "The failure of Instant Runoff to accomplish the purpose for which it was adopted: a case study from Burlington Vermont" (PDF). Const Polit Econ. 34 (3): 378–389. doi:10.1007/s10602-023-09393-1. S2CID 255657135. Retrieved 9 January 2024.
  53. ^ O'Neill, Jeffrey C. (2006). "Everything That Can be Counted Does Not Necessarily Count: The Right to Vote and the Choice of a Voting System". SSRN Working Paper Series: 340. doi:10.2139/ssrn.883058. ISSN 1556-5068. S2CID 155750146. With instant runoff voting ... The strategy for the liberal voter is the same as for plurality voting: Her favorite candidate cannot win, so she casts her vote for her favorite candidate with a realistic chance of winning
  54. ^ Comments (9 December 2016). "The False Promise of Instant Runoff Voting". Cato Unbound. Retrieved 29 January 2017. They'll have a strategic incentive to falsify their preferences.
  55. ^ "2009 Burlington Mayor IRV Failure". bolson.org. Retrieved 29 January 2017.
  56. ^ Graham-Squire, Adam; McCune, David (2022). "A Mathematical Analysis of the 2022 Alaska Special Election for US House". arXiv:2209.04764v1 [econ.GN].
  57. ^ https://www.washingtonpost.com/opinions/2022/11/01/alaska-final-four-primary-begich-palin-peltola/
  58. ^ "House of Representatives Results". Results.aec.gov.au. Retrieved 1 March 2015.
  59. ^ "Every RCV Election in the Bay Area So Far Has Produced Condorcet Winners". fairvote.org. 6 January 2017. Retrieved 13 February 2017.
  60. ^ Travis, Alan (10 May 2010). "Electoral reform: Alternative vote system would have had minimal impact on outcome of general election". The Guardian. London. Retrieved 1 April 2011.
  61. ^ History of Preferential Voting in Australia, Australian Broadcasting Corporation, 2004 Election Guide. "Such a long lasting Coalition would not have been possible under first part the post voting"
  62. ^ Walter, Benjamin. "History of Preferential Voting in Ann Arbor". Archived from the original on 8 February 2012.
  63. ^ "Ann Arbor Law Suit". FairVote. Retrieved 10 May 2011.
  64. ^ Leary, Mal (12 June 2018). "Opposed To Ranked-Choice Voting, LePage Says He Might Not Certify Primary Election Results". www.mainepublic.org. Retrieved 14 January 2019.
  65. ^ "Complaint" (PDF), Baber v. Dunlap (Court Filing), no. 1:18-cv-00465, Docket 1, D.M.E., 13 November 2018, retrieved 13 January 2019 – via Recap
  66. ^ "1st Circuit ends Poliquin's efforts to keep House seat". Bangor Daily News. 22 December 2018. Retrieved 17 August 2019.
  67. ^ Green, Antony (11 May 2010). "Preferential Voting in Australia". www.abc.net.au. Retrieved 1 November 2020.
  68. ^ "What We Know About Ranked-Choice Voting". New America.
  69. ^ Drutman, Lee; Strano, Maresa (10 November 2021). "What We Know About Ranked-Choice Voting". New America. Retrieved 28 February 2023.
  70. ^ Nanson, E. J. (1882). "Methods of election: Ware's Method". Transactions and Proceedings of the Royal Society of Victoria. 17: 206. The method was, however, mentioned by Condorcet, but only to be condemned.
  71. ^ Condorcet, Jean-Antoine-Nicolas de Caritat (1788). On the Constitution and the Functions of Provincial Assemblies (in French). Vol. 13 (published 1804). p. 243. En effet, lorsqu'il y a plus de trois concurrents, le véritable vœu de la pluralité peut être pour un candidat qui n'ait eu aucune des voix dans le premier scrutin. {{cite book}}: |work= ignored (help)
  72. ^ Ware, William R. (1871). Application of Mr. Hare's system of voting to the nomination of overseers of Harvard College. OCLC 81791186. It is equally efficient whether one candidate is to be chosen, or a dozen.
  73. ^ Reilly, Benjamin. "The Global Spread of Preferential Voting: Australian Institutional Imperialism" (PDF). FairVote.org. Retrieved 17 April 2011.
  74. ^ Ware, William R. (1871). Application of Mr. Hare's system of voting to the nomination of overseers of Harvard College. OCLC 81791186.
  75. ^ McLean, Iain (October 2002). "Australian electoral reform and two concepts of representation" (PDF). p. 11. Retrieved 22 February 2008.
  76. ^ Bowler and Grofman, Elections in Australia, Ireland and Malta, p. 40
  77. ^ Farrell and McAllister, The Australian Electoral System, p. 50
  78. ^ Farrell and McAllister, The Australian Electoral System, p. 72, 87
  79. ^ "Australian Electoral History: Voting Methods". Australianpolitics.com. Archived from the original on 19 March 2011. Retrieved 17 April 2011.
  80. ^ "The Origin of Senate Group Ticket Voting, and it didn't come from the Major Parties". ABC News. 22 September 2015.
  81. ^ a b https://archive.fairvote.org/articles/reilly.pdf
  82. ^ The Ceann Comhairle or Speaker of Dáil Éireann is returned automatically for whichever constituency s/he was elected if they wish to seek re-election, reducing the number of seats contested in that constituency by one. (In that case, should the Ceann Comhairle be from a three-seater, only two seats are contested in the general election from there.) As a result, if the Ceann Comhairle wishes to be in the next Dáil, only 165 seats are actually contested in a general election.
  83. ^ electoral votes
  84. ^ "Maine became the first state in the country Tuesday to pass ranked choice voting". 10 November 2016. Retrieved 10 November 2016.
  85. ^ "Ranked Choice Voting | Maine Voters Rank Candidates". Maine Uses Ranked Choice Voting. Retrieved 8 April 2018.
  86. ^ Russell, Eric (12 June 2018). "Mainers vote to keep ranked-choice voting, with supporters holding commanding lead". Portland Press Herald. Retrieved 13 June 2018.
  87. ^ "Alaska Ballot Measure 2, Top-Four Ranked-Choice Voting and Campaign Finance Laws Initiative (2020)". Ballotpedia. Retrieved 17 November 2020.
  88. ^ Sturgis, Alice (2001). The Standard Code of Parliamentary Procedure, 4th ed.
  89. ^ Riddick & Butcher (1985). Riddick's Rules of Procedure, 1985 ed.
  90. ^ "Glossary: Exhaustive ballot". Securevote.com.au. Retrieved 6 May 2010.
  91. ^ "Initiatives – Pew Center on the States" (PDF). Electionline.org. Archived from the original (PDF) on 16 May 2008. Retrieved 6 May 2010.
  92. ^ IRV for Louisiana's Overseas Voters (web page), FairVote IRV America, retrieved 16 June 2013
  93. ^ Antony Green (8 September 2015). Preferences, Donkey Votes and the Canning By-Election – Antony Green's Election Blog (Australian Broadcasting Corporation). Retrieved 8 September 2015.
  94. ^ "Voting system". www.ecq.qld.gov.au. Electoral Commission of Queensland. 28 January 2020. Retrieved 17 November 2020.
  95. ^ Stevens, Bronwyn (27 January 2015). "Are Queenslanders in danger of 'wasting' their votes?". The Conversation. Retrieved 28 November 2020.
  96. ^ "Electoral Systems". Electoral Council of Australia. Archived from the original on 9 March 2008. Retrieved 15 February 2008.
  97. ^ "Ranked-Choice Voting". Registrar of Voters, Alameda County. Retrieved 15 December 2016. This format allows a voter to select a first-choice candidate in the first column, a second-choice candidate in the second column, and a third-choice candidate in the third column.
  98. ^ Breyer, Patrick (November 2013). "Alternative II: Einführung einer Ersatzstimme" (PDF). Anhörung zum Entwurf eines Gesetzes zur Abschaffung der Fünf-Prozent-Sperrklausel bei Landtagswahlen in Schleswig-Holstein [Hearing on the draft law to abolish the five percent threshold in state elections in Schleswig-Holstein (Discussion paper)] (Report) (in German). Piratenfraktion im Schleswig-Holsteinischen Landtag. (Drs. 18/385).
  99. ^ "Dual Level Voting - Granting equal votes in a proportional election with a threshold". www.dualvoting.com.
  100. ^ Nanson, E. J. (1882). "Methods of election". Transactions and Proceedings of the Royal Society of Victoria. 19: 207–208. although Ware's method cannot return the worst, it may return the next worst.
  101. ^ Green-Armytage, James (2004). "A Survey of Basic Voting Methods". Archived from the original on 3 June 2013.
  102. ^ a b "Burlington Vermont 2009 IRV mayoral election". RangeVoting.org. Retrieved 17 April 2011.
  103. ^ FairVote. "Understanding the RCV Election Results in District 10". FairVote.org. Archived from the original on 26 July 2011. Retrieved 17 April 2011.
  104. ^ Smith, Warren D. "Monotonicity and Instant Runoff Voting". Retrieved 4 May 2011.
  105. ^ Lepelley, Dominique; Chantreuil, Frederic; Berg, Sven (1996). "The likelihood of monotonicity paradoxes in run-off elections". Mathematical Social Sciences. 31 (3): 133–146. doi:10.1016/0165-4896(95)00804-7.
  106. ^ Ray, Depankar (1986). "On the practical possibility of a 'no show paradox' under the single transferable vote". Mathematical Social Sciences. 11 (2): 183–189. doi:10.1016/0165-4896(86)90024-7.
  107. ^ Smith, Warren D. "Lecture 'Mathematics and Democracy'". Retrieved 12 May 2011.
  108. ^ "Presidential Election November 1990". ElectionsIreland.org. Retrieved 23 November 2009.
  109. ^ "State Election 2014: Prahran District (Distribution of preference votes)". Victorian Electoral Commission.
  110. ^ "2009 Burlington Mayor Election". votingsolutions.com. 3 March 2009. Archived from the original on 9 November 2009.
  111. ^ Bouricious, Terry (13 March 2009). "Point/Counterpoint: Terry Bouricius Attempts To Rip Professor Gierzynski A New One Over Instant Runoff Voting Controversy (Now With All New Gierzynski Update!)". Vermont Daily Briefing. Archived from the original on 19 October 2015. Retrieved 27 September 2017. the 2009 election suffered from not only the 'thwarted majorities' or Condorcet's paradox, but also the 'no-show paradox' that shows that Wright voters who preferred Montroll over Kiss (that is, ranked Montroll 2nd) would have been better staying home and not voting at all.
  112. ^ a b c d Gierzynski, Anthony; Hamilton, Wes; Smith, Warren D. (March 2009). "Burlington Vermont 2009 IRV mayoral election". RangeVoting.org. Retrieved 1 October 2017. Montroll was favored over Republican Kurt Wright 56% to 44% ... and over Progressive Bob Kiss 54% to 46% ... In other words, in voting terminology, Montroll was a 'beats-all winner,' also called a 'Condorcet winner' ... However, in the IRV election, Montroll came in third!
  113. ^ a b Olson, Brian (2009). "2009 Burlington Mayor IRV Failure". bolson.org. Retrieved 1 October 2017. This is an IRV failure. The IRV result is clearly not what people actually wanted. More people liked Montroll over Kiss than the other way around, but IRV elected the loser.
  114. ^ Sheldon-hess, Dale (16 March 2009). "IRV Fails in Its Own Backyard". The Least of All Evils. Retrieved 27 September 2017. Montroll would have beaten any other candidate in a one-on-one election.
  115. ^ Bouricius, Terry (17 March 2009). "Response to Faulty Analysis of Burlington IRV Election". FairVote.org. Retrieved 1 October 2017. successfully prevented the election of the candidate who would likely have won under plurality rules, but would have lost to either of the other top finishers in a runoff
  116. ^ "Burlington's 2009 Mayoral Election: Did IRV Fail The Voters?". Integral Psychosis. 16 March 2009. Retrieved 1 October 2017. Montroll was the 'Beats-All winner' (aka the 'Condorcet winner') as he would have beaten both Wright (56% to 44%) and Kiss (54% to 46%) in head-to-head races, demonstrating that he was the preferred candidate by the majority of voters.
  117. ^ "Instant run-off voting experiment ends in Burlington". Rutland Herald Online. Archived from the original on 4 March 2016. Retrieved 15 December 2016.
  118. ^ "Burlington, Vermont, Question 4, Ranked-Choice Voting Amendment (March)". Ballotpedia.org. Retrieved 18 April 2021.

Practice

Demonstrations and simulations

Advocacy groups and positions

Opposition groups and positions