Abstract
Free full text
A network-based microfoundation of Granovetter’s threshold model for social tipping
Associated Data
Abstract
Social tipping, where minorities trigger larger populations to engage in collective action, has been suggested as one key aspect in addressing contemporary global challenges. Here, we refine Granovetter’s widely acknowledged theoretical threshold model of collective behavior as a numerical modelling tool for understanding social tipping processes and resolve issues that so far have hindered such applications. Based on real-world observations and social movement theory, we group the population into certain or potential actors, such that – in contrast to its original formulation – the model predicts non-trivial final shares of acting individuals. Then, we use a network cascade model to explain and analytically derive that previously hypothesized broad threshold distributions emerge if individuals become active via social interaction. Thus, through intuitive parameters and low dimensionality our refined model is adaptable to explain the likelihood of engaging in collective behavior where social-tipping-like processes emerge as saddle-node bifurcations and hysteresis.
Introduction
Studies of collective behavior or action, such as protest demonstrations, responses to disasters or even revolution1, fosters an understanding of the formation and logic of the crowd2–5. Broadly, the study of collective behavior can be separated into either that of social movements or that of temporary gatherings. Social movements are usually more structured around specific, identified goals, have deeper social connections between actors, are organized (generally to defend or fight against existing authorities) and persist over time (such as the civil rights movements)6. In contrast, gatherings (such as riots, sudden protests, concerts, sporting events) are more spontaneous, less organized, do not carry as deep of social connections between actors, and can be quite ephemeral7,8.
Further, individual engagement in collective behaviors (such as changing consumption behavior or adoption of new technologies) can be connected to broader social processes, such as norms and expectations for behavior9. Specifically, individuals strategically control their actions in accordance with their norms in order to achieve their goals and objectives4,5,10. As such, norms and preferences structure an actor’s likelihood to engage in collective behaviors, as well as its form of participation within these groups. Complex forms of collective behaviors (be it either a movement or a crowd) are thus created through dynamic interactions of actors that share common goals and objectives for a given social situation. For example, global climate change has been frequently noted as one prominent contemporary social problem that could trigger and might also be addressed through collective behaviour (such as the emergent ‘Fridays for Future’11 movement)12–14.
Empirical evidence for such complex contagion of interlinked individuals leading to collective action has been found for both online15–17 and offline18 social networks. Additionally, complex contagion has been experimentally shown to foster social tipping19, a process that has gained increased attention in the recently20 due to its potential for rapid societal changes with profound impacts on the entire socio-ecological Earth System13,21. Complementing empirical studies, recent conceptual models of complex contagion incorporate the spreading of an action, behaviour or trait through a complex network22–26. They often aggregate an individual’s surrounding over time27,28 or abstract space29 to accumulate exposure to a considered trait such that at a certain point the individual adopts that trait as well. Such models have been applied successfully to study processes involved in the spreading of opinions30,31, large-scale epidemics24, the adoption of life-style choices32 or the collective behaviour of animal groups33,34. However, most such models of collective behavior are often tailored to a specific problem (both in the incorporated processes as well as the underlying parameter set) and are thus often not transferable to different and novel applications.
The Granovetter threshold model is a comparatively early contribution to this field, providing a core basis for subsequent and more contemporary modeling attempts35. This model aims to explain the emergence of collective behaviors while noting that individual norms and preferences are a crucial factor determining their development and final outcome. In particular, when presented with a simple binary choice – to participate within a collective behavior or not – each individual has a certain activation threshold for participation. This measures the proportion of the group that an individual would like to observe participating within the collective behavior before they are willing to join themselves. The thresholds emerge from the norms, preferences, goals and beliefs of each individual, e.g., representing a kind of trade-off between the costs and benefits of joining in the behavior. As such, the application of the threshold model, or variations thereof, is not limited to simple crowd-like behaviors, such as protests and riots, but is comparatively broad, encompassing collective behaviors e.g., voting36, diffusion of innovations37, or migration38, as well as classical social movements such as the Monday Demonstrations in East Germany39. However, while by design the model is very flexible, it has mainly been used for illustrative and theoretical purposes (including most applications outlined above), but hardly applied as a numerical modeling tool.
This paper identifies two major sets of issues that prevent broader application of the Granovetter model and proposes extensions to resolve them. First, under often assumed threshold distributions (such as cut-off Gaussians35) the model usually unrealistically predicts either no-one or the entire population to eventually act. We resolve this issue by drawing from real-world observations, social movement and resource mobilization theories40,41, as well as recent theoretical and numerical results regarding network spreading processes42,43 to extend the original model by classifying individuals as either certainly active, certainly inactive, or contingently active. This causes the model to display nontrivial equilibria in which a certain part of the contingent individuals becomes active. Second, the emergence and shape of the threshold distribution itself is often underexplained. Therefore, we utilize an established conceptual network cascade model29 and show that a broad (non-Gaussian) threshold distribution emerges from microscopic networked interactions in which potentially active individuals join an action if a sufficient number of their neighbors are also engaged. We thus specifically acknowledge empirically observed tendencies of individuals to make decisions with respect to their immediate social surrounding rather than considering the entire global population, i.e., the mean field19,44,45. By addressing both of the above issues, we effectively separate (unique) individual preferences which determine general tendencies towards or against an action from the embedding of each individual into a larger social structure and corresponding exposure to external influences. Both characteristics then co-determine whether the individual ultimately joins into an action or not.
The remainder of this work is organized as follows. We first introduce the formal specifics of the Granovetter threshold model and discusses in detail its aforementioned conceptual limitations. We then implement the proposed solutions and present a refined threshold model that only depends on parameters that are readily observable in real-world systems. Additionally, we provide an analytical solution of the refined model and analyse its potential for modeling social tipping. Ultimately, we culminate with a discussion of the results and an outlook to future work.
Granovetter’s threshold model
The threshold model assigns each individual in a population of size N a threshold that defines the number of others that must participate in an action before the considered individual does so, too35. In its discrete-time formulation the number of acting individuals at time
Note that the original exemplary application of the model was that of individuals’ participation in riots. Hence the choice of the symbol R for the number of acting individuals. An equilibrium number of acting individuals R* is obtained by solving
While the threshold model has been widely used within a broad literature41,46,47 it has up to now been mainly used for illustrative purposes as a number of issues hinder its application as numerical modeling tool:
Plausible distributions typically predict no one or the entire population to act
As thresholds are hard to estimate, one typically assumes Gaussian threshold distributions35 cut off at the extreme values 0 and N. However, assuming a mean threshold μ of reasonable size and a moderate standard deviation σ implies that there are only few individuals with low or high thresholds and many with medium thresholds close to μ. Hence, under the typical assumption of a low number of instigators35 the model usually predicts zero eventually acting individuals, Fig. 1a. Only if a sufficiently large σ is chosen more individuals than the instigators become active. However, the choice of a large σ causes the distribution to become rather flat instead of bell-shaped. For example, for a population size of
In addition, if no individual has a threshold larger than 100%, the threshold model generally has a second typically stable fixed point at
We therefore propose a framework that refines the threshold model and accounts for the above issues by grouping individuals according to basic preferences that determine whether they certainly, contingently or never act. This circumvents the existence of trivial solutions and we show below that this approach does not require a constant updating of the threshold distribution as a response to changing group memberships.
The threshold distribution can not be observed, but emerges from microscopic factors
Broadly, two complementary aspects shape whether an individual engages in an action or not. On the one hand there are individual factors (such as background characteristics, social class, education or occupation48,49), that determine the acceptance of or inclination towards an action. On the other hand there are group factors, i.e., characteristics resulting from one’s embedding in a larger social network (such as social position, influence, or peer pressure50). Both traits and processes ultimately co-determine the macroscopic threshold that is exposed to the observer and we call these thresholds of the original Granovetter model emergent thresholds from here on. However, quantifying the emergent thresholds on the individual basis is difficult, if not impossible, to achieve without any prior knowledge or assumptions on the aforementioned microscopic characteristics and interactions. In addition, even properly justifying a certain shape of the emergent threshold distribution is a difficult task as it remains unclear to which extent different shapes follow from a certain composition of individual traits.
Notably, in analogy to the concept of emergent thresholds there should still exist on the micro-level a share (or number) of others that join into an action before an individual does so, too. One commonly accepted definition of such a quantity is that of a threshold fraction29 that is not assessed with respect to the entire population, but with regard to the relevant social ties of a considered individual35,51. The specific importance of one’s egocentric social network for decision making has recently been shown in empirical studies where individuals generally did not aim for consensus or convergence in the global population, but rather on the microscopic or group-level19,44. Additionally, it was observed that individuals tend to coordinate with (at least subsets of) an entire group rather a single partner45. This renders the use of a per-individual threshold fraction particularly useful as it determines the share of others within a group that must make a certain decision before the considered individual does so, too. In our specific case this threshold fraction is considered a fundamental trait of each individual, regardless of whether their preferences and norms favour or hinder a certain action. As such it disentangles social processes from non-social factors, such as individual preferences and norms. In contrast to the emergent thresholds, these threshold fractions may not necessarily be widespread. Rather, they might be assumed to have a narrow distribution or correspond to fixed, intuitive points, e.g. 50% (majority rule)52. Note that in contrast to the emergent thresholds, that measure absolute numbers in a global population, the threshold fraction measures the relative number of others in one’s egocentric social network that must make a decision before a considered individual does so, too. It thereby specifically accounts for heterogeneities in the number of each individual’s neighbors, i.e., the so-called social network’s degree distribution53.
Below we present a microscopic threshold model based on a previous study of cascading dynamics29 where individual preferences are assigned to each member of the population that then join into an action based on their threshold fractions applied to the neighborhood in their social network. We then show that such microscopic processes in fact yield an often postulated broad (but not normal-shaped) emergent threshold distribution.
Results
Refinement of the Model
We start by addressing the first two issues identified above, namely that for usually chosen distributions the original model predicts either no-one or the entire population to become active. As discussed above, one way to circumvent these issues is to assign certain individuals either a threshold of 0% or ≥100% such that some individuals certainly become active and others never become active35. This approach requires a constant updating of the threshold distribution and may be impracticable for many cases. Recent studies investigated the effects of either such certainly active initiators42 or never active immune individuals43 on the adoption of certain traits or behaviours via spreading dynamics on social networks. In alignment with social movement theory40,41 we combine these two notions and suggest to divide the population of size
If we have no reason to assume that the threshold distribution is different in the three groups, the original recursive formula Eq. (1) is then replaced by
The equilibria of the thus refined model are again obtained by computing the intersection of the r.h.s. of Eq. (2) with the diagonal through
In order to also avoid having to redraw F in Fig. 1b whenever there is a variation in A or C, it is beneficial to rescale the ordinate to the unit interval, Fig. 1c. This allows us to find the equilibria for all possible combinations of A and P in the same diagram, by drawing F only once and just adjusting the diagonal to meet the points
Our adjusted approach makes the application of the threshold model as an actual modeling framework more practical as it (i) produces nontrivial fixed points R*, (ii) requires the threshold distribution to be only estimated once for the entire population or a representative sample thereof, and (iii) relies on only two intuitive parameters, the size of the certainly (A) and potentially acting population (P). Recall that A directly relates to an immediate action or behaviour, while P denotes the general acceptance of or attitude towards that action.
Estimation of the emergent threshold distribution
Having refined the threshold model to properly allow for the computation of non-trivial fixed points, we shift our focus to the second issue that relates to the threshold distribution itself. It has been established above that the emergent thresholds follow from microscopic characteristics of each individual as well as its embedding in a social context. Specifically for the latter it will turn out that the share of others, i.e., the threshold fraction, that must join into an action before a contingent individual does so, too need not be widely distributed or even heterogeneous at all across the population in order to produce a widespread distribution for the emergent threshold.
We now study how such characteristics and interactions on the micro-level determine one’s emergent threshold by using a simulation model of social contagion that has been studied in the past to model binary decisions with externalities and resulting cascading dynamics29. We represent each individual in the population by a node in a complex network and draw links between nodes to indicate their embedding in a social group of others (see Methods section below for details). This relates directly to the idea of a sociomatrix that accounts for the stronger influence that individuals to which one forms a social bond have on one’s behaviour35. In addition to the original formulation of this network cascade model29 and in agreement with the consideration put forward above we assume that P randomly distributed nodes form the potentially active population. Being potentially active subsumes all norms, preferences and attitudes that cause an individual to show acceptance for a considered type of behaviour. Among the P potentially active nodes we assume that
We simulate cascades of nodes becoming active for two different shares of potentially active nodes
To estimate an emergent threshold distribution as required for the Granovetter-type threshold model we now evaluate
By approximating the number of active, ai, and inactive neighbors, bi, of a node i as coming from a common multinomial distribution that only depends on the number of neighbors
here,
Comprehensive analysis and social tipping
From the approximate emergent threshold distribution F in Eq. (3) we estimate the fixed points r* of the refined threshold model for different choices of a, p (or
In summary, our model conceptually shows what has formerly been termed social tipping, i.e., a process where, for a given population, a small change in the size of a dedicated minority can have a large effect19,21,56. In our specific case, for a given value of a or p a small change in the respective other parameter suffices to largely increase (or decrease) the share of finally acting individuals r*. Complementing recent theoretical and numerical studies of spreading processes on networks that either varied the size of the initiating minority42 or the so-called immune group of inactive nodes43 our model shows a bistable regime that is necessary for the emergence of hysteresis. This implies that once the system has tipped it sustains its state of high (low) shares of acting individuals r* even if a or p were to be reduced (increased) again. By incorporating both, initiating and immune groups, our model additionally gives rise to a previously undetected cusp bifurcation as well.
Remarkably, the critical size of the dedicated minority at which the system undergoes a fold bifurcation (Fig. 4a,b) has recently been empirically estimated to lie in the range
Discussion
We have proposed a refined version of the original Granovetter threshold model35 that addresses a set of issues that, so far, have hindered its application as a conceptual modeling tool. Specifically, we propose to divide the considered population of size N into three classes (certainly, potentially, and certainly not acting individuals) of different sizes
Our revised model describes multiple forms of collective behaviors, including social movements and crowd-like behaviors. For both such behaviors, norms are directly called upon to structure individual likelihood to engage in actions while also observing the actions of others around them. Importantly, there are differences in the speed of the process. For crowds the observation of social members is made relatively quickly, as are the decisions to participate in the actions. In contrast, these processes can be much slower for social movements. For both cases, however, we identify three time scales that are underlying our refined threshold model. We assume that the microscopic threshold fractions change at the slowest time scale (usually years to decades), as these are attributed to the unique identity of an individual (which may be less prone to sudden external shocks). In contrast, the classification into certainly or contingently active individuals varies on intermediate time scales (months to years) as changes in the environment (such as financial shocks or the exposition to increasing extreme weather events) are beyond an individual’s own agency and can trigger sudden changes in attitudes64. The social dynamics modelled here, i.e., the observation of others and the joining into an action, are happening on the fastest time scale (days to months) as frequent social interactions are common among members of any given society.
Most parameters of the refined model may be readily measurable in a variety of applications. Attitudes that determine p could be estimated from surveys or existing panel data. The share of certainly acting individuals a could be given by those in the population that inevitably need to act, e.g., migrate as a consequence of climate change impacts65,66. For the average degree K it may often suffice to set it to a reasonable number, e.g., Dunbar’s number that suggests a cognitive limit to the number of people with whom an individual can maintain a persistent social relationship67 (see Supplementary Information for details). The threshold fraction
Future work should concentrate on collecting data for the different parameters and then consequently test and calibrate the model against historical test cases. One specific challenge that lies within such an endeavor is the estimation of appropriate (relative) time scales at which the parameters and the internal variables change. In addition, appropriate early-warning indicators62,68,69 should be applied to study the existence of precursory signals for the transgression of a social tipping point, i.e., bifurcation, in our model. Some of these indicators would require a further extension of the model such that individuals may also spontaneously become active with a low probability even if their threshold fraction is not transgressed (or vice versa). We further acknowledge that up to now a proposal for an emergent threshold distribution has only been derived analytically for the case of an Erdős—Rényi random network70. While this lays good groundwork, the threshold distribution should also be explored for topologies (such as scale-free71 and small-world networks72) that more closely mimic those of real-world social systems. Hence, even though our proposed approximation of the emergent threshold distribution holds well if the system is well-mixed and close to a fixed point, more elaborate methods, e.g., pair approximations55 and moment generating function approaches29, should be used to predict the model’s dynamics for more general network topologies and during transient phases as well. Ultimately, the model should be applied as a conceptual modeling tool, e.g., to make qualitative statements on the possibility for social tipping with respect to issues of global change or sustainability transformations12,73,74 under different scenarios.
Methods
Network cascade model
For the microscopic network simulation we consider an Erdős—Rényi random network70 with
Approximation of the emergent threshold distribution
The approximate emergent threshold distribution F in Eq. (3) is derived by assuming that for each individual i the number of active ai and inactive neighbors bi are distributed according to a common multinomial distribution, giving
P′=N−1−R denotes the number of inactive individuals that are not the considered i, as one’s own level of activity is not accounted for.
Acknowledgements
This work was developed in the context of the COPAN collaboration at the Potsdam Institute for Climate Impact Research (PIK). M.W. and K.S. are supported by the Leibniz Association (project DOMINOES). J.F.D. is grateful for financial support by the Earth League’s EarthDoc program and the European Research Council advanced grant project ERA (Earth Resilience in the Anthropocene). The authors gratefully acknowledge the European Regional Development Fund (ERDF), the German Federal Ministry of Education and Research and the Land Brandenburg for providing resources on the high-performance computer system at PIK.
Author contributions
All authors designed the study. M.W. performed the numerical simulations and analysed the data. M.W. and J.H. derived the analytical approximation. M.W. and E.K.S. drafted the manuscript. All authors substantively revised the work.
Competing interests
The authors declare no competing interests.
Footnotes
Publisher’s note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Supplementary information
is available for this paper at 10.1038/s41598-020-67102-6.
References
Articles from Scientific Reports are provided here courtesy of Nature Publishing Group
Full text links
Read article at publisher's site: https://doi.org/10.1038/s41598-020-67102-6
Read article for free, from open access legal sources, via Unpaywall: https://www.nature.com/articles/s41598-020-67102-6.pdf
Citations & impact
Impact metrics
Citations of article over time
Alternative metrics
Smart citations by scite.ai
Explore citation contexts and check if this article has been
supported or disputed.
https://scite.ai/reports/10.1038/s41598-020-67102-6
Article citations
A Dynamic Network Model of Societal Complexity and Resilience Inspired by Tainter's Theory of Collapse.
Entropy (Basel), 26(2):98, 23 Jan 2024
Cited by: 1 article | PMID: 38392354 | PMCID: PMC11154394
Integrating evolutionary theory and social-ecological systems research to address the sustainability challenges of the Anthropocene.
Philos Trans R Soc Lond B Biol Sci, 379(1893):20220262, 13 Nov 2023
Cited by: 2 articles | PMID: 37952618 | PMCID: PMC10645068
Review Free full text in Europe PMC
Dose-response functions and surrogate models for exploring social contagion in the Copenhagen Networks Study.
Eur Phys J Spec Top, 230(16-17):3311-3334, 01 Oct 2021
Cited by: 0 articles | PMID: 34611486 | PMCID: PMC8484857
Data
Data behind the article
This data has been text mined from the article, or deposited into data resources.
BioStudies: supplemental material and supporting data
Similar Articles
To arrive at the top five similar articles we use a word-weighted algorithm to compare words from the Title and Abstract of each citation.
Emergence of bursts and communities in evolving weighted networks.
PLoS One, 6(8):e22687, 12 Aug 2011
Cited by: 16 articles | PMID: 21857946 | PMCID: PMC3155510
Interplay between tie strength and neighbourhood topology in complex networks.
Sci Rep, 14(1):7811, 03 Apr 2024
Cited by: 0 articles | PMID: 38565614 | PMCID: PMC10987512
Emergence of communities and diversity in social networks.
Proc Natl Acad Sci U S A, 114(11):2887-2891, 24 Feb 2017
Cited by: 9 articles | PMID: 28235785 | PMCID: PMC5358344
Building a collective memory: the case for collective forgetting.
Curr Opin Psychol, 23:88-92, 10 Feb 2018
Cited by: 6 articles | PMID: 29459336
Review